The crisis of bourgeois economics

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Mon Aug 21, 2023 3:04 pm

Stigler Center/ProMarket Hypocrisy: Published, Then Removed Post That Justified Anti-Trust; Bogus Excuses Demonstrate University of Chicago Failed Econowashing of Hard Core Neoclassical Stance

Posted on August 21, 2023 by Yves Smith

Yves here. The post below on intellectually dishonest behavior by the University of Chicago Stigler Center’s ProMarket publication and three academics is more important than it seems at first blush. As we will discuss, it shows that what looked like a to put a kinder, gentler face on neoclassical economics, which in layperson terms is strong-form neoliberalism, is a sham, an exercise in econowashing. ProMkarket published, then retracted an analysis that disproved the economic logic of the current anti-trust standard, that the only basis for backing anti-trust measures if if they will increase output. That finding should not even be controversial. Yet the shifting and nonsensical excuses for yanking the piece strongly suggest the real reason was that it bucked party line.

The Stigler Center, created in 1977, kicked into a higher gear of activity a few years ago, by among other things sponsoring a series of fellows, many of whom were not card-carrying neoliberals, and hosting conferences that again looked intended to go beyond the University of Chicago faithful. The Stigler Center website depicts it as wanting to promote competitive markets to benefit general welfare. While it’s not hard to see that as anti-labor, it should also entail opposition to rentier activities and monopolization.

One of its publications, ProMarket, has similarly encouraged economists who are well outside the neoclassical/neoliberal fold to contribute pieces. But now that anti-trust is a hot topic thanks to Lina Khan at the FTC. And now that the Department of Justice and the FTC have published draft merger guidelines, we are seeing the Stigler Center and ProMarket’s true colors.


By Darren Bush, Professor, The University of Houston Law Center Faculty; Mark Glick, Professor, University of Utah; and Gabriel Lozada, Associate Professor of Economics, University of Utah. Originally published at the Institute for New Economic Thinking website

Image

A central aim of Neoliberalism was to dismantle the antitrust regime put in place after World War II whose central goal was to protect democracy, small business, local control, and to prevent transfers of income from labor to large corporations with market power. The principal mechanism for limiting antitrust enforcement was the Consumer Welfare Standard popularized by Judge Bork and University of Chicago economists. The Consumer Welfare Standard restricts antitrust goals to preventing decreases in consumer surplus. In practice, this means the goal of antitrust is solely to increase output. The justification rested on an outdated and flawed theory that human welfare was advanced by more output alone, a theory that virtually every welfare economist has since abandoned, and one that only survives in some dusty industrial organization textbooks. The theory is defective because it ignores distribution: in the antitrust world, a dollar transferred from labor to a monopolist has no welfare implications. We have written several papers published by INET and professional journals about how fallacious this approach is.1The response from Chicago partisans, not surprisingly, has been to ignore the issue.

Then we submitted a two-page blog to ProMarket, a publication of the University of Chicago’s Stigler Center, housed in the Booth School of Business. Our two-page blog demonstrated that even in the most general neoclassical model, an output increase is not sufficient to increase welfare. Allocation—how goods are distributed—matters.

Our original post started with a production possibility frontier (PPF) and a social welfare function. The figure showed an outward shift of the PPF, an output increase. If there is no additional step of optimizing allocation, points below B or to the left of A would represent a decrease of social welfare.

Image

We next offered an Edgeworth Box example, which makes the same point if no social welfare function is defined.

Image

The point of this figure is to show that an increase in output can decrease the individual utility of every person if output is allocated in certain ways.

ProMarket accepted the post and published it. But then something strange happened. An anonymous board member demanded to Editorial Board member Professor Luigi Zingales that it be retracted. At first, we were told our proof was wrong because if you fully optimize and welfare only depends on consumption and all the Arrow-Debreu assumptions are in place, then welfare increases. That one can pile assumptions on top of each other enough to increase welfare is obviously true but beside the point. The response actually implicitly proves our point – that output alone is insufficient.

We responded that whoever had complained should write a signed blog post critiquing our post. We also offered another version of the graphs in which there was no optimizing in the initial position, together with corresponding textual revisions; the conclusions were unchanged. ProMarket staff informed us that while they were prepared to post it as an update to our piece, alas Professor Zingales still felt it was not enough to have a proof that simply shows a possibility.2 Staff asked if we would like to withdraw the piece despite it being already published.

We declined. We then received an email from Professor Zingales. It stated that the original graphs didn’t have an equilibrium and that if the social welfare function is maximized then the proof doesn’t hold. Done right, output alone does increase welfare. Therefore, the proof is wrong.

What followed was a phone call with Professor Zingales and two of the authors. Zingales conceded that the point was in fact a correct description of the feasible set, but insisted that a description of the feasible set, without a full-fledged behavioral model that would specify exactly where on the feasible set the economy would end up, was not worth publishing.

The retraction was carried out with the following unsigned note to readers. We agreed to the language, as we were concerned that ProMarket would put a retraction notice out there that would injure our reputation. That would cause us to pursue litigation. The language reads:

ProMarket published the article “The Antitrust Output Goal Cannot Measure Welfare.” The main claim of the article was that “a shift out in a production possibility frontier does not necessarily increase welfare, as assessed by a social welfare function.” The published version was unclear on whether the theorem contained in the article was a statement about an equilibrium outcome or a mere existence claim, regardless of the possibility that this outcome might occur in equilibrium. When we asked the authors to clarify, they stated that their claim regarded only the existence of such points, not their occurrence in equilibrium. After this clarification, ProMarket decided that the article was uninteresting and withdrew its publication.

A recognition that output increases alone do not increase welfare is interesting, outside of the University of Chicago. It reveals that the opposite contention, which is a central tenet of the Consumer Welfare Standard, crucially depends on very particular modeling and equilibrium assumptions, because without those assumptions, increasing output may fail to raise welfare. The Consumer Welfare Standard is an important obstacle holding back antitrust policy from progressive reform. Many progressive economists have made the case that increased market power has caused irreputable harm to the economy and to the social fabric of the United States. For example, Professor Joseph Stiglitz has written on the importance of allocation. He states: “A closer look at those at the top reveals a disproportionate role for rent-seeking: some have obtained their wealth by exercising monopoly power…” Similarly, Thomas Philippon has demonstrated that increasing wealth inequality decreases reinvestment. Among non-mainstream economists that Chicago routinely ignores, Brett Christophers has documented an increased concentration of assets into the hands of a few, the rentier class.

Some ProMarket contributors have questioned the removal of our piece. Professor Herbert Hovenkamp questioned why the piece was removed when others have made similar points. As Professor Steve Salop noted, the second set of graphs we submitted should have taken care of any problem ProMarket had with the piece.

All of us know from Carl Sandberg that Chicago is a city of big shoulders. Its eponymous economics school has no business shrugging off so central a point. Of course, our conclusion is important, which is why ProMarket initially published it. The claim that it is of no interest is transparently a desperate effort to shore up a doctrine that is now collapsing.

The full piece is available at The Sling.

Notes

1.See, e.g., Mark Glick and Darren Bush, “The Chicago School, The Post Chicago School and The Neo Brandeisian Schools of Antitrust in Light of Modern Economics,” available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm ... id=4417509. Mark Glick, Gabriel Lozada, and Darren Bush, “Why Economists Should Support Populist Antitrust Goals” 2023 Utah L. Rev. 769. Mark Glick and Gabriel Lozada, “The Erroneous Foundations of Law & Economics,” available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm ... id=3812839; and Darren Bush and Mark Glick, Breaking up Consumer Welfare’s Antitrust Policy Monopoly, 56 Suffolk L. Rev. 203 (2023).
2.This is a close paraphrase of the communication we received, including the regretful “alas.” We would be very happy if ProMarket released its side of the correspondence to the public.

https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2023/08 ... tance.html
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Sat Sep 09, 2023 1:58 pm

Image

Believing one’s own false theories
By Prabhat Patnaik (Posted Sep 08, 2023)

Originally published: Peoples Democracy on September 10, 2023 (more by Peoples Democracy)

LIBERAL bourgeois writers tend to explain the problems that arise under capitalism not by the immanent tendencies of the system but by the capriciousness of particular governments. This way they can continue to believe in their own false theories that prettify capitalism, while putting the blame for the travails it generates on political bloody-mindedness. One such instance of prettification is the portrayal of the system as one where international trade is beneficial for all. Centuries of colonialism which played havoc with the economies of the conquered countries, causing poverty, unemployment and underdevelopment, by forcing an exploitative trade relation upon them, should have left no scope for such prettification, but colonialism alas never figures in bourgeois economics.

Now, one obvious assumption, among many, that underlies the belief that international trade benefits all, is that all countries experience full employment of all “factors of production” (including labour), both before and after trade. Trade just leads to a change in the bundle of goods that is produced by fully using all the factors that were also fully used earlier; this change involves for each country greater specialisation in the production of those goods where it has a “comparative advantage”. Through trade therefore, the world output, taking all countries together, increases, and this is what creates the possibility of all countries benefitting from trade. The worst that can happen to any country in this situation is that it may not gain from trade; but there is absolutely no reason why it should lose from it.

But, far from there being full employment of all factors both before and after trade, capitalism on its own is characterised, as one exceptional liberal bourgeois economist, John Maynard Keynes, had recognised, by an almost perennial demand constraint, that is, by a perennial state of over-production, or what he called “involuntary unemployment”. Trade in such a case becomes primarily an instrument for exporting unemployment to one’s trading partner, by running an export surplus vis-à-vis it; the stronger the demand constraint, and the more acute the situation of unemployment, the greater would be struggle among countries to export unemployment to one another. In this struggle, unemployment would also be sought to be exported to countries which may not themselves be capitalist.

The neoliberal order involving relatively unrestricted flows of goods and service and of capital, including finance, across country borders, had been set up on the bourgeois argument that trade was beneficial for all, so that neoliberalism, being conducive to trade, was supposed to benefit all. But after the collapse of the American housing bubble when the world economy got into a protracted crisis of over-production (that is, experienced serious demand constraint), the game of protecting one’s own economy against imports of goods began in right earnest. The idea was to produce at home the goods that were hitherto imported, and thereby increase domestic employment at the expense of employment abroad (which amounts to exporting unemployment to them). And the same metropolitan economies that had arm-twisted the third world to accept the neoliberal order, took the lead in protecting themselves against imports by violating the rules of the same neoliberal order. The country specifically targeted was China which had been a shining example of export-led growth; such exports had been achieved to a significant extent under the aegis of metropolitan capital that had located itself in China and was exporting back to the metropolis.

Western liberal bourgeois economists see protectionism against Chinese goods as being caused by political bloody-mindedness vis-à-vis China, and attribute western violation of neoliberal rules to this bloody-mindedness; in fact, however, it is the crisis of over-production, which is a result of the immanent tendencies of capitalism, that underlies such protectionism, and not any pure political desire to punish China. There may well be such a political desire too, but to see that alone as giving rise to protectionism in the west is to exonerate capitalism from its immanent contradictions, and to perpetuate the fable that, but for this act of victimisation, free trade would have continued and been beneficial for all.

Such frantic attempts to export unemployment through the pursuit of what are called “beggar-my-neighbour” policies, had characterised the period of the Great Depression of the 1930s. Government spending to boost aggregate demand was not tried during much of the 1930s anywhere, other than in the fascist countries that had armed themselves in preparation for the war. Roosevelt’s New Deal was no doubt introduced during the early1930s, but was promptly truncated the moment the US economy showed some signs of recovery, leading to a resumption of the crisis. It is only when war appeared imminent that the liberal capitalist countries went in for government spending on armaments. But before large-scale government spending was undertaken,exporting unemployment through “beggar-my-neighbour” policies was pervasively resorted to, with competitive exchange rate depreciations characterising most countries after they had gone off the gold standard; but since everybody was trying such “beggar-my-neighbour” policies, it was not much of a success for overcoming depression in any single country. Protectionism in the third world however, especially in Latin America, sowed the seeds of import-substituting industrialisation in that continent. The crisis thus acted as the harbinger of industrialisation in the third world.

We are once more seeing a move towards protectionism in the metropolis now under the guise of an attack on China’s export success. But it is not a case of geo-political rivalry spoiling the wonderful regime of free trade that neoliberalism had ushered in, as the liberal economists would have us believe; rather, it is protectionism as a response to the crisis, as a means of exporting unemployment, that is being directed against what is perhaps the most strikingly successful exporting country in the world. Geo-political rivalry provides an alibi; the US can argue that it believes in the free trade that it preaches, but has to reckon with geo-political realities because of which it is imposing protectionist measures against China. The truth however is the other way round; under the cover of geo-political rivalry it is engaged in exporting unemployment to China through its protectionist measures.

China is unlikely to be greatly handicapped by American protectionism; it has been diversifying its production away from the export to the home market for some time now, in anticipation precisely of such an eventuality of western resistance and also to ward off domestic peasant disaffection. In fact, some years ago it had adopted a document called “Towards a Socialist Countryside” that visualised much higher State spending in rural China.

This entire episode highlights the pitfalls of a strategy of export-led growth in today’s context: if a country, especially a large country, is successful in achieving a high rate of export-led growth, then it would sooner or later invite resistance from the metropolitan economies. So far we have talked about resistance arising only in the context of an over-production crisis. But even when there is no marked over-production crisis, the persistence of an export surplus vis-a-vis the leading imperialist country on the part of a successful exporting country, which leads both to a loss of jobs from, and greater indebtedness of, the former to the latter, would also invite resistance from the leading country.

Even before China, Japan, which posed no geo-political challenge to the US, had suffered a similar fate: its great success in achieving export-led growth had eventually led to American resistance to Japanese exports, bringing down Japan’s rate of growth. It is possible to argue that the current American measures in the context of the Ukraine war also constitute an instance of such resistance against Germany’s success in achieving export-led growth: the blowing up of the Nord Stream pipeline which makes any resumption of cheap Russian gas supplies to that country nearly impossible and thereby raises costs of production of German industry, knocks out all prospects of reviving German export success in the foreseeable future.

Of course merely cutting out imports is not enough to generate growth; it raises employment and output but in a once-for-all manner. There has to be a perennial exogenous growth stimulus to generate sustained growth in the economy. Increasing government spending, if financed either by a fiscal deficit or by taxes on the rich, can provide such a stimulus; but globalised finance capital typically opposes both such ways of financing larger government spending. The leading metropolitan country therefore will have to do much more than merely protecting its economy against imports, to overcome the crisis.

https://mronline.org/2023/09/08/believi ... -theories/
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Fri Jan 05, 2024 4:21 pm

The World in Economic Depression: A Marxist Analysis of Crisis
OCTOBER 10, 2023

Notebook no. 4 was researched and written by E. Ahmet Tonak (an economist at Tricontinental: Institute for Social Research) and Sungur Savran (an instructor at Istanbul Okan University and editor of Devrimci Marksizm and Revolutionary Marxism).

The production team for this notebook, from editing to translation and design to our website upload, includes: Vijay Prashad, Celina della Croce, Mikaela Nhondo Erskog, Deby Veneziale, Pilar Troya Fernández, Maisa Bascuas, Emiliano López, Dafne Melo, Luiz Felipe Albuquerque, Cristiane Ganaka, Tings Chak, Ingrid Neves, Daniela Ruggeri, Amílcar Guerra and Ariana Hereñú.

INTRODUCTION
We are going through a period of profound uncertainty, morosity, and destitution. This is true even in imperialist countries, where the number of people in need of food banks is constantly increasing. In Britain, packs distributed by food banks more than doubled from 1.1 million parcels in 2015/16 to 2.5 million in 2020/21, with close to a million packs going to children in need.1The Trussell Trust, ‘End of Year Stats’, April 2021–March 2022, https://www.trusselltrust.org/news-and- ... ear-stats/.

This does not mean, of course, that everyone is suffering. The net worth of billionaires around the world grew by more than $3.6 trillion in 2020, boosting their share of global household wealth to 3.5% even as the pandemic pushed approximately 100 million people into extreme poverty.2Tami Luhby, ‘As Millions Fell into Poverty during the Pandemic, Billionaires’ Wealth Soared’, CNN Business, 7 December 2021, https://edition.cnn.com/2021/12/07/busi ... index.html.

The inequality that capitalism inevitably produces has created a world in which the richest 2,153 billionaires have more wealth than the poorest 4.6 billion people who make up 60% of the population on the planet.3Oxfam International, ‘World’s Billionaires Have More Wealth than 4.6 Billion People’, 20 January 2020, https://www.oxfam.org/en/press-releases ... ion-people.

These twin trends are not peculiar to the impact of the pandemic: they have been going on for years, indeed for decades, woven together by the laws of capitalism in crisis.

In this notebook, we seek to shed light on the profound crisis of the world economy that has been unfolding for more than a decade. Explaining the crisis is not a meaningless exercise for the benefit of displaying the technical dexterity of professional economists. Rather, it is necessary to go beyond superficial manifestations to discover the essence of the entire process. In this way, we can shed light on the path forward for the working classes of all countries and the oppressed nations of the world in their struggles to turn back the tide of destitution and misery. In an effort to provide tangible and concrete results for the proletariat and the wretched of the earth, it is important to explain the inherent contradictions of capitalism that give rise to these crises. Incorrect explanations can only mislead the masses and harm their struggles.

It is common knowledge that the capitalist world economy experienced a severe financial convulsion in 2008, which has come to be known as the global financial crisis. The bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, one of the big Wall Street investment banks, sent shock waves across the world, bringing the international financial system to a total collapse. Christine Lagarde, France’s finance minister at the time (later to take on the posts of managing director of the International Monetary Fund and then president of the European Central Bank), warned US Secretary of the Treasury Hank Paulson that they must not allow the sprawling insurance company American International Group (AIG) to fail immediately after Lehman Brothers.

The crisis was triggered by the bloated housing market, especially in the Global North (not only in the US, but also in Britain, Spain, Ireland, and other countries), a result of pushing mortgages even to consumers who would patently not be able to pay them back. Not only did the so-called sub-standard mortgage market, which had reached entirely unrealistic values, collapse, but, because these mortgages had been packaged into derivative products in financial markets in forms such as collateralised debt obligations and collateralised loan obligations, this collapse brought, in its wake, the collapse of other financial markets and left many banks and other types of financial institutions facing the precipice.

The name ‘global financial crisis’ was, at first, used exclusively to depict the profound crisis that the collapse of Lehman Brothers triggered in the world economy. However, it rapidly became a misnomer, as it became clear that the crisis was not peculiar to the sphere of finance but extended to the so-called real economy – in other words, the sphere of production. Steep, and to a certain extent unprecedented, decline was soon observed in such key variables as growth and investment as well as in a catastrophic rise in unemployment in many countries (at its worst, two European Union members, Spain and Greece, experienced youth unemployment that skyrocketed to more than 50% for years on end). Hence the ruling circles of the capitalist economy and governments began to use the neologism ‘the Great Recession’, coined by the Frenchman Dominique Strauss-Kahn (DSK, as he was known in financial and government circles), then the managing director of the IMF.

Image

We refrain from using the term ‘great recession’ simply because, in our opinion, this was a smokescreen meant to hide the true nature of the crisis. A ‘great recession’ is something of an oxymoron. Recessions are conventionally defined as rather brief periods lasting longer than two quarters (or six months) that are fixed on a single economic variable, the rate of growth, when the latter enters the negative zone – in other words, when the economy shrinks. It is true that the world economy, as well as single national economies, did shrink immediately after the ‘global financial crisis’. However, many other factors were in play that are not encapsulated in the narrow technical concept of ‘recession’. ‘Great recession’ is an oxymoron simply because one cannot make the strictly narrow concept ‘recession’ do more work than the technical job for which it was invented. The appellation great recession was, in fact, invented by DSK to prevent state dignitaries, financial pundits, and the economics profession from using the ‘d-word’, i.e., depression.

The fact that the term ‘great recession’ was a smokescreen is also evident when one remembers what the alternative designation would have been. Alan Greenspan, who served as the chairman of the US Federal Reserve Bank for almost two decades, was among the most orthodox defenders of the rationality of markets and of capitalism. He made a lucky escape by retreating out of his role as the chairman of the US Federal Reserve Bank in 2006, thereby saving himself from being seen as the official directly responsible for the ‘Great Recession’. He was among many to say that this was a ‘once-in-a-century financial crisis’, a clear reference and comparison to the Great Depression of the 1930s. Thus, the ‘Great Recession’ concedes the ‘greatness’ of the crisis to conceal the fact that it was a depression.

Historically, capitalism has experienced different types of crises of varying intensity and duration. The most common among them generally occur roughly once in a decade and have conventionally been studied and referred to in professional literature as business cycles (the specialist writing on business cycles is outside the central core of mainstream economics for reasons we will be explaining in a moment). The culmination of a business cycle is, as a rule, a recession, a brief period during which the economy shrinks. This type of crisis is usually overcome through the adjustment of market forces, which has also been assisted to a certain extent by government policy since the post-war period in the second half of the twentieth century.

A depression is a different type of crisis in the history of capitalism. It lasts much longer, sometimes for a decade, sometimes for several decades. It cannot be managed and overcome through the conventional adjustment of market variables and requires radical convulsions not merely in the economic sphere, but also in the political, ideological, and even military domains. When a depression unfolds at the level of world capitalism, the convention, until now, has been to call it a great depression. The first such crisis – referred to as the ‘long depression’ at the time – took place at the end of the nineteenth century, approximately between 1873 and 1896. The second is the familiar Great Depression that began with the crash of Wall Street in 1929 and spread far and wide all throughout the 1930s, lasting, for many countries, especially those in Europe, until the end of the Second World War in 1945. In the opinion of many Marxist economists, including the authors of this notebook, the prolonged and profound crisis that we are experiencing today is also a great depression.

Image

THE DIMENSIONS OF THE CURRENT CRISIS
While the entire world has been experiencing economic malaise for a decade and a half, the trajectory and depth of the current crisis differ across countries and regions with diverse socioeconomic structures and varying positions in the world economy. The imperialist countries, for good reason as we shall see, were the origin of the crisis, and their populations suffered greatly throughout this entire period in terms of economic growth, investment, unemployment, and labour productivity. The United States displayed a trajectory of its own, recovering to a certain extent after 2013 and sustaining an edge over other imperialist countries, in particular Eurozone countries and Japan, until 2019, when it began to experience a slowdown. This would soon be coupled with the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic, which began to spread with force in early 2020 as successive shutdowns took their toll on the country’s economic performance.

The so-called emerging countries (those that have been industrialising at a rapid pace over several decades or come from the background of a centrally planned economy), such as Argentina, Brazil, India, Mexico, Russia, South Africa, and Turkey, underwent a completely opposite trajectory from that of the United States. Having been shaken to some extent by the initial shock of the financial turbulence set on by the 2008 crisis, these countries soon recovered under the perverse mechanisms of capitalist finance to attain, at least in some instances, an economic performance beyond anything they had so far experienced. To take one example, the Turkish economy, after having shrunk during the first year of the crisis, recovered quickly to achieve, for the next two years, the highest growth rates the country had ever attained. The reason for the leap in economic performance in these countries did not necessarily have to do with their own policies. The most effective instrument that imperialist countries had to cope with the crisis was a policy of cheap and abundant money pursued by central banks, which made credit plentiful in these countries. However, since they drastically reduced interest rates for the same reason, finance instead flowed to countries where much more could be earned, namely the emerging countries. Thus, the bane of a world in crisis proved to be a boon for a certain group of countries whose economies were propelled by the inflow of all types of foreign liquidity. However, as the US economy began to recover in 2013, the Federal Reserve Bank changed its cheap money policy. This new policy orientation by the US Federal Reserve Bank initiated a period of hard times for emerging countries.

Though the less, and the least, developed countries faced differing scenarios, overall, they suffered seriously from the fall in international trade, which meant a reduced demand for their staple export products and an even higher decline in foreign direct investment. The price of primary commodities also took a beating. However, this had a differential impact on countries depending upon, for instance, whether the country was an importer or exporter of energy. In most of these countries, the overall impact was the accumulation of a mountain of foreign debt.

One country, however, was a category of its own: China. Although it considers itself to be a developing country, China has not suffered the same fate as the rest of the Global South, having maintained extremely high growth rates for decades based on its internal dynamics as well as its interaction with the rest of the world economy. Even since 2013, China has persisted as the single case that seems to demonstrate what many experts call the ‘decoupling’ of emerging countries from the imperialist ones.4For more on the concept of ‘decoupling’ or ‘delinking’, read Tricontinental: Institute for Social Research’s interview with Samir Amin, Globalisation and Its Alternative, notebook no. 1, 29 October 2018, https://thetricontinental.org/globalisa ... ternative/.

Whatever the variety of experiences of different groups of countries, certain trends have inevitably had an impact on all groups in the long run.

Since 2008, there has been an overall slowing down of the economy both internationally and at the level of the richest imperialist capitalist economies (see figure 1).

Image
Data from Michael Roberts, The Long Depression: Marxism and the Global Crisis of Capitalism (Chicago: Haymarket, 2016), 115.

Investment, which had already been on the decline for a long time, took a nosedive in the period after 2008. Moreover, during the post-2007 period the average annual labour productivity growth rate in the G7 countries has hovered around 1%, a dismal performance compared to the 2% average rate from 1971–2006 (see figure 2).

Image
Our calculations are based on data from the Organisation for Economic Cooperation Development.

Given this reality, whatever dynamism existed derived from the policies of governments and central banks in imperialist countries that aimed to achieve a quick recovery of the world economy. This took two forms: monetary and fiscal.

In the sphere of monetary policy, the central banks of imperialist countries followed in the footsteps of the US Federal Reserve Bank in aggressively pursuing a policy of cheap and abundant money. They did this in two different ways. The first was by reducing the reference interest rate all the way down to zero in many cases and even into the negative zone in others (see figure 3).

Image
Data from Olga Kuznetsova, Sergey Merzlyakov, and Sergey Pekarski, ‘Confidence in Future Monetary Policy as a Way to Overcome the Liquidity Trap’, Russian Journal of Economics 5, no. 2 (July 2019): 117–135, https://doi.org/doi:10.32609/j.ruje.5.38703.

The second was that the central banks pursued a policy dubbed quantitative easing, which involved the purchase of government bonds in the open market – i.e., going to the printing press. Quantitative easing was nothing but a hypocritical euphemism for printing money that was not backed by corresponding developments in the real economy. This manifested itself in skyrocketing growth rates in the central banks’ balance sheets.

On the fiscal policy front, the United States and Eurozone poured vast amounts of money into government expenditure programmes that sought to recover the economy (see figure 4).

Image
Data from Adam Tooze, Crashed: How a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World (New York: Viking, 2018), 355.

Naturally, deficit spending and a policy of cheap money create liabilities in the long run, as expressed in the snowballing debt of the major imperialist economies (see figure 5). Extraordinarily high levels of debt, which surpassed the 120% mark in 2012, signalled the highest public indebtedness in the entire history of the capitalist mode of production, breaking the record of wartime indebtment (see figure 5).5Murray E. G. Smith, Jonah Butovsky, and Josh J. Watterton, Twilight Capitalism: Karl Marx and the Decay of the Profit System (Halifax: Fernwood Publishing, 2021), 61.

By April 2023, US national debt had reached the staggering amount of US$ 31 trillion, which represented 124% of GDP.

Image
Roberts, Long Depression, 68.

At around the same time, the 18 Eurozone countries had a debt-to-GDP ratio of 97.7%, although this varied wildly between the Mediterranean countries (Greece and Italy, for instance) and the countries of northern Europe.6Eurostat, ‘General Government Gross Debt – Annual Data’, accessed 22 April 2022, https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrows ... le?lang=en.

It is important to note that public debt is not the only burden facing the economies of imperialist countries: private corporate debt also rose immensely both before and after the global financial crisis (see figure 6).

Image
Guglielmo Carchedi and Michael Roberts, eds., World in Crisis: A Global Analysis of Marx’s Law of Profitability (Chicago: Haymarket, 2018), 321.

As a result of this extreme policy of what is called pump-priming (i.e., stimulating an economy in recession), new bubbles are building up in stock exchanges and various markets such as housing, which have all grown at paces that are wildly incommensurate with the development of the real economy. Certain reliable experts on stock markets, such as the Nobel laureate Robert J. Shiller, have warned against being too sanguine about the ‘roaring 20s’ of the twenty-first century, since the previous roaring 20s of the twentieth century ended in the Black Tuesday of 1929, ushering in the Great Depression of the 1930s.7Robert J. Shiller, ‘Looking Back at the First Roaring Twenties’, The New York Times, 16 April 2021, https://www.nytimes.com/2021/04/16/busi ... tocks.html.


Unforeseen events can also take a toll on economic cycles. For instance, the COVID-19 pandemic has certainly impacted the economic cycle and made predicting future patterns more difficult. Another example of unpredictability is the war in Ukraine, which is also taking its toll on the world economy. In addition to the direct impact of the war, including convulsions in the markets of energy, metals, and foodstuffs, in which Russia and Ukraine are key players, the extraordinary level of sanctions imposed by Western countries on Russia and the boycotting of the Russian domestic market by Western companies have amplified the disruption of the world economy. It is no exaggeration to say that a decade and a half after the 2008 Lehman Brothers moment, the world economy is still in a sorry state.


EXPLAINING CRISES: MAINSTREAM ECONOMICS
Let us inquire into what mainstream economics has to say about crises under the capitalist mode of production. As soon as we turn to mainstream bourgeois economics for its characterisation of crises, we immediately come face to face with the utterly ideological and apologetic character of this discipline. An overwhelming part of mainstream economics is built on the assumption that economic crises are ruled out because of the fundamental laws governing the capitalist economy. There are, of course, dissenting voices, and we will come back to them. But it is noteworthy that, for two full centuries, since Say’s Law was advanced in the early nineteenth century, the bourgeois economics profession has overwhelmingly denied the possibility of systemic crises under capitalism. Though the rationale for this denial in technical terms has changed over time, the denial itself has remained consistent throughout. Let us then call this the denialist school.

THE DENIALIST SCHOOL
Say’s Law, the brainchild of the French economist Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832), is quite simple. It advances the idea that since all production under the capitalist division of labour is geared towards an exchange between the goods that each agent produces, it follows that all production creates a demand of equal magnitude of value for other goods, and hence all production creates its own outlet (Say called this the ‘law of outlets’). According to this law, total supply is thus necessarily equal to total demand, and so it is impossible for the economic cycle to be interrupted.

Image

It is notable that David Ricardo (1772–1823), the greatest figure in the classical school of political economy alongside Adam Smith (1723–1790), adopted Say’s Law, which is, in fact, a vacuous tautology that does not stand up to even the slightest scrutiny. We shall come back to that shortly, but let it be said that, for half a century, Ricardo provided this supposed law its pedigree. Ricardo himself was not very optimistic about the historical prospects of capitalism. His theory of land rent shows that as capitalism progresses, land that is less and less fertile or more and more distant from metropolitan areas will have to be brought into cultivation. This process will necessarily raise the prices of foodstuffs, thus causing an inevitable fall in the rate of profit and, therefore, stagnation. However, this theory does not address capitalism’s periodic crises.

Neoclassical theory, which is currently the orthodoxy in mainstream economics, has faithfully subscribed to the denialist school of thought. From its rudimentary beginnings in the 1870s, when it was known as marginalist economics, until the general equilibrium theory developed in the wake of the Second World War and the rational expectations theory of the late twentieth century, the denial of economic crises was the hallmark of neoclassical economics.

Today, mainstream economists no longer present Say’s Law as the rationale to explain crises. What has taken its place is an argument alleging the smooth functioning of markets. This argument is based on the mechanism of market clearing prices (the assumption that demand and supply find an equilibrium price point). However, this assumption of the market clearing prices leaves no space for excess or insufficient demand. The recent concept of the efficient market hypothesis reproduces these earlier arguments with little elaboration. Stripped of technical jargon, all this implies is that capitalist markets are so rational and efficient in their functioning that they leave no space for gluts, deficits, or crises.

The reader may well be wondering how the economics profession came to terms with the fact that, throughout the entire history of capitalism, this denial has coexisted with the very real experience of capitalist crises. As we hinted at earlier, this was done through the development of a specialised literature on business cycles, which studies the seesaw-like alternation of growth and contraction within the capitalist economy at regular intervals. However, it must be emphasised that this quite sophisticated literature, which has recourse to a set of complicated technical tools, has never pierced through the thick ideological skin of the mainstream, the result of which would have been to question the efficient market hypothesis.

The economics profession’s alternative justification for the concrete occurrence of crises in the real world has either been to deny that there is a crisis worth naming (reducing the turbulence to a ‘correction’, a term borrowed from the professional jargon of stock exchange analysts), to attribute the crisis to an ‘external shock’ (war, revolution, an unexpected jump in commodity prices, extraordinary meteorological circumstances, etc.), or, most commonly, to mistakes in economic policy. As Karl Marx (1818–1883) wrote, ‘the apologists content themselves with denying the catastrophe itself and insisting, in the face of their regular and periodic recurrence, that if production were carried on according to the textbooks, crises would never occur’.8Karl Marx, Theories of Surplus Value, part 2 (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1968), 500.
FOOTNOTE

There is an interesting anecdote that sheds light on this divorce between theory and reality in mainstream bourgeois economics. After the 2008 global financial crisis, Queen Elizabeth II of the United Kingdom visited the illustrious London School of Economics and Political Science (LSE). Like a naïve child asking the most untoward question in polite company, she asked the eminent economists gathered for the occasion – among them professors at the most prestigious universities, government advisers, and pundits for highly regarded organs of the financial press such as The Economist and Financial Times – the following question: ‘Why did no one see it coming?’.9Ann Pettifor, ‘I Blame the Queen for This Crisis’, The Guardian, 26 February 2009, https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfr ... capitalism.

There was no satisfactory reply. The duty of these eminent economists, up until the 15 September 2008 collapse of Lehman Brothers, had been to defend the impeccably rational functioning of markets in the face of criticism from their hapless less orthodox colleagues, choosing not to reply to Marxist criticism so as not to lend it legitimacy.


KEYNES AND THE REALIST SCHOOL
The denialist school has never been the only current in mainstream economics. From the beginning, some economists held a more sceptical attitude towards Say’s Law, an outlook led by two very different figures: Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi (1773–1842), a social critic in Say’s own country, France, and Thomas Malthus (1766–1834), an extremely conservative parson in Britain and a friend of the liberal David Ricardo. Despite their uninterrupted correspondence on economic matters, Malthus was not able to convince Ricardo of the vacuity of Say’s Law. Ignoring exceptional figures such as William Stanley Jevons (1835–1882), a prominent representative of the marginalist school, and the towering figure of John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946), a British public intellectual and economist who has to this day remained the major representative of what we will call the realist school, the Ricardo position on the question of crisis lingered all the way to the Great Depression years of the 1930s.

In his justifiably famous General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (1936), Keynes attacked Say’s Law head on and advanced the idea that the economy could in fact reach an overall equilibrium in a variety of different situations, such as when faced with underemployment or inflationary overheating on the one hand and a state of full employment on the other (which orthodox theory assumes to be the inevitable point of equilibrium).10John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (London: MacMillan, 1936).

This diversity of possible outcomes was, in his mind, what made his theory a ‘general theory’.

A crisis, according to the scheme developed by Keynes, is a state in which aggregate effective demand (i.e. demand at the societal level that is backed by money) is insufficient to create full employment. It is hence a state of underemployment and underutilised productive capacity. At first sight, this description suggests to the public that Keynes was talking about a lack of consumption power in society because of the poverty and destitution of the working masses. In fact, a broad school of thinking ranging from mainstream Keynesians all the way to a powerful tendency among Marxist economists draws the conclusion that a crisis can be overcome by raising wages and benefits. This is what is conventionally called underconsumptionism. We will come back to it shortly when discussing the diverse Marxist schools of thought. But, for the moment, let us remain within the boundaries of mainstream economics.

It is true that earlier critics of Say’s Law were underconsumptionists. Malthus even went so far as to claim that economic crises are caused by a structural lack of sufficient demand and that, to fill this gap, there needs to be a class of people who do not produce but only consume the revenue that accrues to them not for work but for other ‘services’ to society. However, to think that Keynes was a follower of Malthus would be a most unfortunate misunderstanding in the history of economic thought. Keynes was not an underconsumptionist. His entire corpus of thinking was centred around the decision process of the capitalist class, focused not on consumption but on investment. Keynes is a false friend that underconsumptionists cling to, and not always innocently, since Keynes can be a very powerful ally in pushing for certain policies. He himself was very clear that investment, not consumption, was the prime mover in the functioning of the capitalist economy.

Among mainstream economists, Keynes stands out for admitting that, because there are times when a drop in investment creates an underutilisation of the productive capacity and labour force of a country (or of the world economy as a whole), crises are part of the overall functioning of the economy. He then moves into the domain of the economic policies that governments can pursue in order to overcome such crises. Keynes is most famous for advocating not only for the type of monetary policy that many governments have pursued during the present-day crisis, but also, and very unconventionally for his day, a policy of government expenditure in the sphere of fiscal policy that seeks to stimulate economic activity.

Later, during the long post-war boom that lasted for roughly three decades (1945–1975), Keynesian fine-tuning policies accompanied a rise in state expenditure in advanced capitalism primarily in the spheres of education, health, housing, transportation, and other social services, also referred to as the social wage or the net social wage (i.e., the net taxes paid by the working population). This created the illusion that Keynesianism was some sort of social democracy promoted for the benefit of the working class. However, this is far from the truth: Keynes was a liberal bourgeois thinker who even advocated for a certain level of inflation in order to bring down real wages, which he alleged would make the recruitment of additional labour more attractive for capitalists, thereby reducing unemployment. Thus, the widespread thinking that Keynesianism is the perfect method to fight against crises in the name of labour is an illusion. It is certainly true that a rise in state expenditure under crisis conditions is a way forward so long as it is in the correct areas, such as education and health, for instance, rather than the military, but this fight need not be waged under the banner of Keynesianism.

Image

The problem with Keynes’s explanation of crises is, in a nutshell, that his explanation for fluctuations in the volume of investment over time leaves much to be desired. Because his analysis of monetary theory is revolutionary in nature, the evolution of money and finance was a decisive factor for Keynes. Keynes brought into the picture different facets of capitalists’ calculations about the future, in particular their comparison between the expected returns from their capital investments (i.e., marginal rate of efficiency of capital) and the rate of interest, which is the cost of their capital outlay. Ultimately, he found that the determining factor for policy is in ‘expectations’ since both factors, ‘expected returns’ and ‘the rate of interest’, must be taken up in terms of their future development. This obviously begs the question of what determines expectations themselves, to which Keynes’ heroic reply was ‘animal spirits’.11Keynes, General Theory, 161.

Marx criticised Ricardo, the greatest bourgeois economist of the nineteenth century, for escaping into the field of agronomy in his theory of land rent because he had no overarching economic law of motion based on the particularities of the capitalist mode of production. Similarly, Keynes, the greatest bourgeois economist of the twentieth century, remained in the sphere of circulation and disregarded the relations of production under capitalism (and, in particular, its specific class structure). Without a theory of production, Keynes failed to determine the rate of profit and thus the pace of accumulation independently of the expected rate of interest. Instead, he took refuge in the field of psychology (‘animal spirits’) in order to explain the laws of motion of capitalism.

SCHUMPETER AND CREATIVE DESTRUCTION
There are always mavericks. Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950), an Austrian by birth, was decidedly a nonconformist among the economists of the twentieth century. For one thing, although he was a staunch defender of the capitalist system, he was deeply influenced by Marx’s thinking. For another, unlike most mainstream economists, even more so than Keynes, he was not a narrow-sighted specialist who shut himself within the technicalities of the economics profession. Schumpeter tried his hand in international relations (generating an original, if utterly failed, theory of imperialism), political philosophy (looking at capitalism, socialism, and democracy), sociology (investigating the role of the family in the formation of social classes), and other fields. He was the perfect example of the well-rounded intellectual of turn-of-the-century Vienna, where he lived as a young man.

Schumpeter’s theory of crisis (in the form of a theory of business cycles) has remained influential to this day, especially due to his original idea of ‘creative destruction’, and has become one of the most popular and widely discussed (if not sufficiently digested) explanations of the current crisis. To understand Schumpeter’s originality on crises, it is best to turn to the opening section of his book on business cycles:

Analysing business cycles means neither more nor less than analysing the economic process of the capitalist era. … Cycles are not, like tonsils, separable things that might be treated by themselves, but are, like the beat of the heart, of the essence of the organism that displays them.12Joseph A. Schumpeter, Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process (New York: McGraw Hill, 1939), v.

The title of his 1939 book from which this quote is drawn, Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process, makes it clear that studying business cycles is, in effect, studying the capitalist process itself. This sets Schumpeter apart from all the great mainstream economists – even from Keynes, who did not treat crises as integral to the essential workings of the capitalist system. For Schumpeter, on the other hand, the category ‘business cycle’, or ‘crisis’, is the kernel that makes for the beauty of this particular social formation, propelling the productive forces to continuously develop.

Innovation, for Schumpeter, whether technical, socioeconomic, educational, or otherwise, is the driving force of all human progress. Capitalism is distinguished from all previous formations because it makes innovation an indispensable element of its functioning, which it achieves through the very mechanism of crisis. Crises periodically cause the destruction of the previously accumulated productive forces, which then create both the need and possibility to fill this evacuated space with new productive forces that are of a superior quality and productivity because they embody the fruits of new scientific research, technological application, and innovation. This is the famous process of creative destruction, which makes capitalism an endlessly advancing force in history, always reaching out towards new horizons.

In many ways, Schumpeter’s vision of capitalism is quite similar to and was likely very much influenced by Marx, which is why he has been called a ‘bourgeois Marxist’.13George Catephores, ‘The Imperious Austrian: Schumpeter as Bourgeois Marxist’, New Left Review, no. 205 (May–June 1994): 3–30.

Both in The Communist Manifesto (1848), co-authored with Engels, and in volume one of Capital (1867), Marx had already emphatically and almost panegyrically stated that capitalism cannot exist without constantly revolutionising the means of production. This influenced Schumpeter’s thinking. What we do not know is whether Schumpeter was also aware that Marx envisioned crisis as the moment when capitalism, through the destruction of the established means of production, makes way for the new and more productive means of production, since Marx’s remarks on crisis are scattered across so many different writings, most of them not yet published when Schumpeter was writing Business Cycles in 1939.

Image

According to Marx, the constant revolutionising of productive forces under capitalism prepares the ground for socialism. Schumpeter, however, saw the constant revolutionising of productive forces as an everlasting benefit that capitalism provides to humanity. His ideological defence of capitalism has two aspects. On the one hand, by making crisis a category that serves the progress of humanity, Schumpeter provided a justification for the devastation and misery caused by capitalism. On the other hand, his theory led to a one-sided understanding of crises: he limited the destructive force of capitalist crises to the means of production, whereas it is perfectly possible that these profound crises may well move society towards the destruction of the social relations of production. To put it differently, the spasms of crises may also prove to be the birth pangs of a new, classless society. The idea of creative destruction is thus formulated so as to preclude the more radical destruction that can be caused by crises – that of revolution, capable of creating not only new means of production, but a new society. Hence, Marx’s theory of crisis contains but also supersedes Schumpeter’s insight into the functioning of the capitalist mode of production.

EXPLAINING CRISES: MARX AND THE MARXISTS
The Marxist theory of the capitalist economy recognises the central place of crises in the historical motion of this mode of production, which is one of the most salient reasons why the Marxist analysis of capitalism is superior to mainstream economic theory. As we shall see, not only did Marx give due recognition to crises, which are a most common phenomenon of capitalist development, rather than denying their systemic nature, but he also went further and analysed them as the pivot on which the fate of the capitalist economy and society hinges.

MARX’S THEORY OF CRISIS: AN INTRODUCTION
To start with, Marx refused to grant even the slightest validity to Say’s Law. This was in stark contrast with the theories of Ricardo, post-Ricardian economists, the theoreticians of the ‘marginalist revolution’ of the 1870s (Stanley Jevons, Karl Menger, and, most importantly, Léon Walras), and the entire neoclassical school of economics that gradually formed in the footsteps of the marginalist school. Despite this, Keynes did not give Marx the credit he deserves, though he praised Malthus at length for his insight into how a possible lack of effective demand can lead to a crisis. Keynes’s bourgeois prejudices are likely the only reason that he underestimated Marx. In his General Theory (chapter 23, section VI), Keynes took up Silvio Gesell (1862–1930), an idiosyncratic figure in the history of monetary theory and the finance minister of the short-lived Bavarian Soviet Republic in 1919. It is in the context of a comparison with Gesell that Keynes put forth his only assessment of Marx, writing, in reference to Gesell’s main work, The Natural Economic Order (1916):

The purpose of the book as a whole may be described as the establishment of an anti-Marxian socialism, a reaction against laissez-faire built on theoretical foundations totally unlike those of Marx in being based on a repudiation instead of on an acceptance of the classical hypotheses, and on an unfettering of competition instead of its abolition. I believe that the future will learn more from the spirit of Gesell than from that of Marx.14Keynes, General Theory, 355.
FOOTNOTE

Has anyone heard of Gesell in the twenty-first century?



Marx attacked Say’s Law for disregarding the possibility that sellers of commodities can delay their purchase of other commodities. Say based his reasoning on the fact that all commodity producers engage in production activities with the purpose of selling the commodities that they have produced in order to purchase other commodities. Hence, whoever sells buys. In the aggregate, this means that demand is created by supply. Marx pointed out the simple mistake here: although it is true that supply creates the capacity to purchase goods and services, the act of purchase is a separate transaction from the act of sale, since the two are mediated through the conversion of the value in question from the commodity-form to the money-form and back. Sellers may very well decide to withhold the money they have thus acquired. If a sufficiently large number of sellers were to decide that it is to their benefit to keep their money and spend it sometime in the future (i.e., hoard their money), there would be a shortcoming in the demand for the goods produced, triggering the possibility of a crisis. In other words, Say reduced the unity between sale and purchase that is mediated by money into an unmediated or direct relationship between supply and demand.

As we mentioned earlier, Marx regarded crisis both as a problem for capital accumulation but also as a solution. What we mean by this is the following: all crises of a sizeable magnitude reveal the contradictions within the process of capital accumulation, which are concealed during times of heady profit-making. As soon as accumulation slows down, all kinds of shortcomings and inadequacies of varying severity come to the surface. Among these, of course, is the fact that the means of production are undergoing moral depreciation and cannot continue to serve the capitalists who use them as the basis for their competitive effort in the market, whether domestic and/or international. Here, Marx and Schumpeter were in agreement.

Another aspect where Marx and Schumpeter agreed is that the destructive aspect of crisis contains within it a solution to the crisis at hand. According to Marx, any major crisis requires a solution to two problems. The first is that measures must be taken to raise the general rate of profit. The second is that the means of production that are subject to moral depreciation, that are no longer competitive, and that lag behind new and more productive capacity must be eliminated in order to give way to a new set of machinery and equipment and new methods of production. The modality of elimination of old productive capacity takes the form of what Marx called devalorisation (Entwertung in the German original). To explain the term briefly, Marx used the term valorisation (Verwertung) to refer to the process whereby production adds new, additional value to the object of labour through the expenditure of living labour. Since valorisation refers to the process of augmenting value, devalorisation refers to a loss in value, which can even reach the loss of the entire value. Through this process, the capital embodied in a plant, machinery, or equipment loses or sheds its quality of value to become worthless and can thus no longer serve as productive equipment. This is Schumpeter’s analysis of the destructive process of crises. The elimination of old, obsolete, or insufficiently productive machinery and equipment as a result of crises is also of fundamental importance in Marx’s analysis.

Marx, and the Marxists who follow his analysis, make a fundamental distinction between the triggering factors that cause a disturbance in the economy, which may then set off a chain reaction that transforms a minor disturbance into a major crisis, and the crisis itself, which is always different from the triggering element. A perfect example of this is when a rise in the price of oil provoked a major crisis in 1973–1974, which led to the onset of a long, depressive period of slow accumulation. However, the real cause behind that crisis of accumulation was the fall in the rate of profit over an extended period of time due to the progressive replacement of living labour by machinery and automation. Another more recent example is the subprime mortgage crisis that began in the US in 2007 and spread to the rest of the world in 2008–2009. The subprime mortgage aspect of the crisis was simply the detonator of a devastating collapse in the financial system, which had expanded well beyond the productive base of the real global economy. We will return to this mechanism in more detail below. For now, let it be noted that the tendency of bourgeois economics to attribute the root cause of crises to their triggering factor has resulted in great confusion among the public about the nature of crises.

There are many aspects to this dialectic between the real processes that cause crises within capital accumulation and the outward manifestation of these crises. One such aspect is the question of overproduction. Whether Keynesian or Marxist, all theories of crisis that identify capital formation (or investment) as the key element in the coming about of major crises acknowledge that crises start in the form of a glut of unsold commodities. However, certain observers of this fact deduce from the existence of these masses of unsold goods that crises are, in their essence, crises of overproduction. Such confusion between the essential processes that lead to crises and the outward appearances of the source of a crisis may lead to serious misunderstanding about crises.

Image

https://thetricontinental.org/dossier-n ... ic-crisis/

(Much more, this is just the half of it.)
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Sat Jan 27, 2024 4:36 pm

Why Does Russia Produce More Ammunition Than the US?
Posted on January 27, 2024 by Yves Smith

Yves here. Nima of Dialogue Works uses the inability of the US (actually the entire Collective West, as described in late 2022 by Alex Vershinin of the Royal United Services Institute) to match Russian artillery output as a point of departure with Richard Wolff and Michael Hudson to discuss the shortcoming of late-stage capitalism. They come to a similar conclusion to the one Andrei Martyanov has made energetically: US arms makers are profit-driven while the Russian military procurement system (even allowing for occasional corruption scandals) is purpose-driven.

Below is the first part of this talk.

By Nima. Originally published at Dialogue Works



Dialogue works (Nima): when it comes to capitalism, they’re talking about that capitalism is by far the most effective and productive economic system. Ohio Senator, James Vance, just recently said that Russia produces as much ammunition in a day as the U.S. does in a month. what’s the problem with the U.S. economy that they’re not capable of producing enough ammunition to help Ukraine?

Richard D. Wolff: Well, let me begin with a comment. I do not believe it is an exaggeration to say that the spokespersons for every economic system in the history of the world have included people who say that whatever system they are, the spokesperson of is the best and the most efficient and the most equitable and the most and the most fill in the blank with positive adjective.

This is childish, and yet you would imagine that a reasonably mature people would get beyond this kind of cheerleading if they’re involved in a serious conversation. It is actually very easy to show whether you are looking at ancient tribal economy or village economies or slave economies or feudal economies that they had their areas where they were remarkably efficient side by side with areas where they were remarkably inefficient.

Assuming that there is a standard that enables you to distinguish between them, which frankly, I don’t believe there ever was or is.

Let me explain briefly,

When you notice that there’s profitability in a particular industry and the CEO, all of the CEOs in that industry are asked, why are you profitable? And they give that wonderful answer that they should have outgrown in fourth grade.

We’re a very efficient company here. The only appropriate response is laughter. Why? Well, what does efficiency mean conventionally in economics? Efficiency purports to do the following thing. It looks at the consequences of some act. Let’s take a, for example. Is it sufficient to expand the hospital to add a new wing to that hospital or for a company?

Is it efficient to buy a fleet of trucks or to hire 50,000 more people or whatever, whatever the issue is? Here’s what you taught. You look at all the benefits that flow from this act and you look at all the costs of this act and you compare them. If the benefits are larger than the cost, why then it’s efficient and you go ahead and do it.

And if the costs are better than or larger than the total of benefits, well then it’s inefficient and you don’t do it. Okay. All right. Now, here are two simple problems. And here I’m simply talking basic philosophy. Or if you like, basic mathematics. How do you know all of the costs or all of the benefits of anything that has ever happened or that could ever happen?

And the answer is, you cannot do that. And no one ever has. Part of the reason is that costs and benefits lie in the future, and it’s kind of hard to get a good number on what they will be. And if there is an economist who knows what the costs will be. Well, then that economist is going to become very rich because they have figured out how to tell the future, which of course is a scam.

They can’t do that. Number two, the costs and benefits are infinite in number and variety. To go back to my example. Suppose there’s a hospital considering building a new wing. Well, if they build that new wing, it will change traffic patterns in that area. Change traffic patterns will alter, real estate prices change, traffic patterns will change. The number of people that get injured or die in automobile accident.

How in the world can you know in advance what all the costs from doing this are? And the answer is you cannot. So here is what all cost benefit analysis has in common. They are frauds because they cannot do what they claim to do. What they actually do is look at a selection of the costs that you can do and a selection of the benefits that you can do.

But then the only interesting thing is the principle of selection, because it isn’t a comprehensive comparison. Long story short, if you do any serious investigation, then you cannot evaluate the efficiency of any economic system and the people who claim that it is the most efficient are giving you the use a technical term total bullshit. And they ought to be called on the carpet for doing that.

There is. It really is kind of childish. CBS did the report 60 Minutes back in May of last year, and in that report, they showed that the Defense Department of the United States is a place that doesn’t have enough ammunition because the company is producing defense equipment, you know, planes, ships, missiles, guns are engaged in. And you can see the statements there from all the relevant officials.

Price gouging and the price gouging is not modest, but price gouging is outrageous. And they give you the figures. They’re a price that’s 100 times what it ought to be or more. Here is the irony. It’s not that Russia can produce what we can produce. My guess is the United States cannot produce Russia. Let’s remember the GDP with all the problems which we have discussed about what the GDP means.

But the GDP of the United States is 21, $22 trillion, and the GDP of Russia is one and a half trillion dollars. We are talking about vastly different industrial systems. And the reason why the United States doesn’t have enough ammunition and by the way, that is part of the reality of why Russia is doing as well in the war in Ukraine as it is.

It’s not because they produce more or better, it’s because they don’t have and this has going to affect a lot of Americans if they take this seriously. They don’t have the level of corruption that we do. We have outdone them. And you know what this is like. This is the same story that has afflicted every empire in human history.

This is the story of why the Romans could not defeat the barbarians in the fifth century. It’s why medieval kingdoms fell apart. It’s not because they couldn’t produce enough knives and guns and spears and all the rest of it, but that the internal mechanisms of the system made it no longer functional and bullshit like efficiency calculus is part of the mental corruption, if you like, these make-believe categories.

We look back on the Middle Ages and we smiled to one another when decisions were made by kings and queens who consulted their advisers, who read the appropriate passage in the Bible to find the answer. We think we’re better than that. The Bible, we say, was a book. There were lots of books. I picked that one. Yeah, well, the notion that you can do the right thing by following Jesus is exactly on a par with the notion that you can do the right thing by choosing the official alternative, as if you were in a position to do that.

I used to tell my students all the training in the world will not enable you to leap over the Empire State Building. You just can’t jump over it. So you don’t bother training to do what you know you can do. Why do we train people in cost benefit analysis? It is a mirage. It is an ideological exercise in order to sanction whatever decisions are made for altogether different reasons by pretending they have been authorized by an objective outside absolute, totally true arbitrator.

Well, in medieval times that was called God. Today we call it efficiency analysis. It is the same fantasy.

Michael Hudson: Well, I think that you don’t have to look at the future in order to make projections. I think efficiency is in the eye of the beholder. Boeing, for instance, is much in the news. And Boeing found it very efficient.

Instead of making airplanes that were adjusted to new fuel-efficient engines, it found it more efficient to make airplanes and crashed to the executives. That was efficient because they could use their money instead of changing the engineering around, instead of building a new airplane. They could use the revenue that they were getting simply to do for stock buybacks and to pay out of dividends.

So that was very efficient, you know. And in terms of prices, of course, you can forecast prices if you’re in a monopoly position and you can charge whatever you want. You decide what price you’re going to charge. It’s at your will. And you can you have control over costs, especially it’s the government. That’s what the Pentagon capital system is.

That I think was really what the interview was talking about under Pentagon capitalism. I think a decade ago it was making a toilet seat for $20 and charging 30 $500 for it. But now they’re even more egregious overruns. It’s very efficient if you’re a Boeing or another military contractor. It’s not efficient for the whole economy. So, I think the really the real question, since our talk is about capitalism versus socialism is what’s efficiency under capitalism and what’s productive and productivity?

Well, the textbook presentation of industrial capitalism says it’s very efficient and it was efficient in the 19th century. It was more efficient than feudalism. And that was really what industrial capitalism set out to be. To cut it, not to raise the costs of Pentagon capitalism and what you’re talking about, but to cut costs in it and cut the economy’s overall costs by getting rid of the landlord class.

So instead of paying land rent to a hereditary aristocracy, you would use that as the tax base. You would essentially get rid of monopoly rent and you’d get rid of financial rent. In other words, what made capitalism efficient was that it was moving toward socialism and it was moving toward socialism by having the government take the lead in providing basic needs for the what?

For the cost of living and for the cost of doing business so that the employers didn’t have to pay them. These costs were to be paid essentially by progressive taxation of the wealthiest property owners and the wealthiest finance shell operators. And I think as we discussed the last time, the income tax in America in 1913 fell, only on the wealthiest 1%.

So, in the 19th century, industrial capitalism certainly looked productive to the extent that it was supporting a mixed economy, a private public economy that was moving towards the government, producing all of the communications, education, health services, transportation that could otherwise be monopolized or that labor would have to pay for and hence the employers would have to pay for.

So, the question is, you know, what went wrong or what went wrong was that the the rent recipient class fall back and they fought back for the last century, ever since World War Two and especially since the 1980s, we don’t have industrial capitalism anymore. Sometimes it’s called monopoly capitalism, but I prefer to call it finance capitalism because banks are the mother of monopolies and it’s the financial sector that has promoted monopolies because they can efficiently make money much, much easier simply by charging whatever they want and not having to take the customers into account, not by producing good materials.

Efficiency today is a race to the bottom. If the race to the bottom in employment, it’s a race to the bottom. Inequality. It’s a race to the bottom for Boeing making airplanes that sudden that don’t really have much oversight and regulatory control and they their doors blow open and they crash. So, again, we’re living in a world where the whole concept of efficiency changes and productivity is no longer simply the physical productivity of output per man hour.

It’s how do you create wealth and you create wealth and being productive in the way that Goldman Sachs had said that Goldman Sacks Partners or the most productive workers in the United States because they make the money and they make the most money financially, they make the most money by taking over companies, breaking them up, smashing them down, and then slowly industrializing them.

So today, the most efficient capitalism is post-industrial capitalism or finance capitalism. You say it’s corrupt and they say, no, we’ve just made politics a free market. And if Boeing and other military spending people have the ability to back the campaigns of the congressmen on the military, on the military committees and the monopoly committees and if they don’t back what we’re doing, if they criticize us, we’ll just use the free market to back their political opponents in the next primary election. So, again, what is efficiency? It’s no longer what it used to be.

Richard D. Wolff: There’s a point that Michael made that is recognized, at least in the textbooks in economics. It’s one of those topics that you blow through in 10 minutes of some lecture and never return to it, because it is embarrassing if you return to it, since it invalidates most of the rest of the semester’s work.

It’s a distinction between private profitability and social profitability or private costs and social costs. And the argument is really very simple. Let’s take a situation where a capitalist decides it is, quote unquote, more efficient. I am going to buy this new machine, and that will allow me to fire 50 workers because the new machine can do what those 50 workers used to do.

So, our capitalist compares the machine only costs 100 and the money he saves by firing 50 workers is 200. So, he’s ahead. If he buys the machine and fires the workers. So, he does. There’s a net gain to him of 100. The difference between the money he had to lay out for the machine and the money he saved from firing the work, though, is simple, very logical.

Now the question, are we done? Have we now seen an efficient act, as are capitalists pursuing the profitable outcome made the right decision? Well, to do that, we’d have to look at the costs and the benefits. And let me tell you about the costs. They are not just the buying of the machine by Mr. Capitalist. The costs are everything that happens to those 50 workers, their spouses, their children, the neighborhood they live in, the real estate values of the homes they occupy, the viability of the stores they used to patronize.

I could go on. We know from a thousand studies that those 50 unemployed people will have higher rates of alcoholism, spousal abuse, mental physical injury and illness. All that costs society is going to have to bear those costs. The doctors, the social workers, you know, the difficulties, the fired workers children are now going to have in school because there’s turmoil at home, because a mother or father or out of work, nobody can sit it because capitalism refuses to take any responsibility for those 50 workers.

We in the world of analysis, thinkers, professors, whatever we are, we are supposed to somehow blindly go along with complete bullshit that we are finished when we compare the cost of the machine that automates with the loss of those jobs. And the minute you don’t do that, the minute you admit that their social costs are not exhausted by those private costs that are counted by the capitalist, remember, he only counts what he has to pay for.

The only thing he has to do is pay for the new machine. He doesn’t have to pay for the mental health counseling of the children, of the fired workers. Not his responsibility. So, for him, that cost does not exist. But for those of us that are interested in the community as a whole, the costs do exist, and a system that constantly pretends otherwise is going to mean making one decision after another.

That is the end of vision, because if you look at all the costs, they far exceed the benefits. And here’s what’s worse the benefits flow to one part of the community and the costs are borne by another part of the community, making it a political explosion of what’s going on here. Automation is profitable all to the employer class, and it is an enormous burden and cost to the employee class.

And because of that, it comes back and bites the employer in the rear end as well. It is a social economic disaster, and if you were honest in economics, you’d know that, and you wouldn’t teach the rest of the course on the premise that profit as an incentive is some successful mechanism. It isn’t. It’s idiotic.

Michael Hudson: Well, when you talk about social costs, you’re really talking about the long run costs in the sense of what are the results of this automation you’re talking about.

But finance lives in the short run, and if you have corporations controlled by the financial sector, they live in the short run and they don’t care about financial costs. And even more they try to make the government pay the cleanup costs. You can take for instance, oil for fracking. It pays for the oil frackers to pump chemicals into the ground to force the gas or oil up to the surface.

And the result is to pollute the water supply so you can light a match to the water that comes out of your tap and it catches on fire. For the oil companies and for the financial for the banks and the financial investors, this is a very this is high productivity you can take. And if you have the financial sector writing the laws that shape the marketplace, you have something like the Trans-Pacific Partnership.

That said, suppose you have an oil company that pollutes the land. For instance, of Ecuador or in Kazakhstan. If a government passes a law saying now the oil company has to pay the cleanup costs of cleaning up the pollution that it’s caused in the waterways or in the land, they have to reimburse the company for the entire fund because that’s an external economy.

Well, what you’re talking about, Richard, is, though, the external economy is society, so that if a government imposes a cost that benefits society at the cost of the American foreign investor or any other foreign investor, that’s against the law legally and no government and end up receiving any money for the clean-up costs that it doesn’t have to immediately pay.

Right back into the company. So in effect, the role of government is to protect the polluters and to protect what you call profits, and I call economic rent, because increasingly, the profits of oil companies and mining companies and monopolies are unearned income. They’re not they’re not producing value. They’re producing a right to charge whatever you want to charge so that you don’t have to project the value of something in terms of the costs, the labor costs and the raw material cost.

Again, you’re getting a free lunch without working, without producing value just by collecting rent. And of course, the GDP accounts, the national income accounts calls all of this earnings. But they’re not really earned income, they’re not profits. Again, they’re economic rent. And that’s the kind of rent seeking economy that we’ve come into. It’s a tunnel vision of the economy.

You call it corrupt. The economics are corrupt. They’re really tunnel vision. They don’t want to take in the social costs because that would reduce the returns to the financial owners of the companies that are imposing these costs on society at large.

Richard D. Wolff: If I could add, I agree completely, but I want to take it kind of another step, if I could. There is a bizarre phenomenon going on here that we should understand.

When Michael says that the government is called in to clean up, the government is called in to protect the government is called in to serve, whether it’s the cap, the employer class as a whole or a subdivision of it that gets into a dominant position like finance capital in recent decades.

Here’s the remarkable thing about that. Not only is the government called in to bail out the failed capitalist system. Let’s all remember in 2009, all of the major banks in the United States, the big ones were bankrupt by the definition of liabilities relative to assets. They were busted. They could not. They didn’t trust each other to give each other overnight loans the way they normally do every day because they weren’t confident that Bank of America or Citibank or Wells Fargo would give back in the morning what was lent to them the night before, because they might do on Lehman Brothers or a Bear Stearns or any of the others that folded.

Okay. Okay. Here’s the wonderful part about that. At the same time that the government is the servant, the faithful, desperate servant of the employer class, it develops an ideology which says that capitalism is a perfect system, except when the government messes up. We call these people because they like the label libertarians but have nothing to do with liberty.

It’s an ironic Aldous Huxley kind of inversion of the word meaning. This has nothing to do with liberty. This is a hustle. This is a person selling you a major interest in the Brooklyn Bridge. Blame the government. Brilliant. Every flaw that capitalism has. You can now admit and use it to beat up on the government with the effect that all the government is left with the responsibility of doing is bailing out capitalism’s failures.

Because otherwise it has been beaten to death with demonization as if it were the problem. Most of the people who will become powerful in the United States if Donald Trump wins the election, it will be libertarian infused policy makers who are going to act on this lunacy with, by the way, the predictable results, which are not pretty.

Michael Hudson: I’m glad you mentioned the concept of liberty and libertarians.

You’re absolutely right. Libertarianism supports a centrally planned economy, much more centrally planned than a mixed economy. More centrally planned than an economy like China. But the central planning is done not by elected government officials, but by Wall Street and the financial sectors. So when people say they’re a libertarian, they say they want liberty from government regulation so they don’t have to follow rules to protect society.

They want liberty from being taxed so that it’s labor and the productive sectors that are taxed, not the corporate sector and the financial sector that owns the sector. So, the question is liberty from whom? And this is what again, the language has been inverted from what it was during the heyday of industrial capitalism from Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill and Marx into just the opposite.

The way to respond to these guys is, again, the meaning of words. And that’s what made George Orwell discussion of double think and double speak so great.

Richard D. Wolff: Enormously important, this topic, because these are not just pathological behaviors. These are not just the objects of what Michael and I can say critically.

These are symptoms of a system that is done, that is overreach, peak, that is in decline. Holding on to these nonsensical ideas becomes irrational because the system is spinning out of control. Here you have a again, I’m going to use Ukraine, even if it provokes some people. On one side, the United States, the G7, Britain, France, Germany, Italy, Canada, Japan and the United States.

I come blind to GDP and again, without lauding that statistic, it’s just a very rough measure. But a combined GDP, by my count, about $32 trillion in a war in Ukraine with a country, Russia with a GDP of one and a half trillion dollars. This is a joke. What kind of war is this? This is David and Goliath.

Only their day that we’re Goliath is ridiculous. And the fact that it isn’t that the Russians have actually won the war, at least so far, tells you that something is terribly amiss. Mr. Zelensky is explaining that they don’t have enough ammunition. They’ve used up the shells, the tanks, the missiles, not just from the United States, but from Britain, France, Germany and so on.

What in the world is going on? How does a one and a half trillion-dollar economy find itself inadequately producing, what, $32 trillion worth of economy is? Right. Something is crazy here. And I think that is where people ought to take this kind of thinking. If a university is teaching people that there is an efficiency, you learn how to count costs and benefits.

This is the exact modern equivalent of having taught medieval scholars how to count the number of angels that dance on the head of a pin. Angels have no dimensions. The head of the pin is very small. But how many angels can very small accommodate an infinity if they have no dimensions? Those And then what? Debates about this.

And we think it’s funny, but I can assure you in the future there’ll be people who look back on this nonsense about efficiency and the nonsense about libertarianism shaking their heads in disbelief that reasonably educated adults got caught up in this sort of stuff.

https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2024/01 ... he-us.html

Pretty much correct, just don't ask these guys to demand something be done about it, like ending capitalism by any means possible as soon as possible. They will hem and haw and reveal their liberal conditioning. And the capitalists smile, free speech is satisfied and nothing happens, business as usual.
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Mon Jan 29, 2024 3:07 pm

Looting of Boeing Set to Continue, Epitomizing Decline of Late-Stage AngloSphere Capitalism
Posted on January 29, 2024 by Yves Smith

Tolstoy wasn’t quite right when he said each unhappy family was unhappy in its own way. Boeing’s accelerating rate of customer-profit harming and passenger-inconveniencing product defects represents an unusually pure and adulterated form of executive looting of a company. However, this pattern of behavior is common in Corporate America in its less extreme form.

Boeing’s unusual position as a “must have” player in a duopoly making perceived-to-be essential products where no way, no how can any other company take up Boeing’s production in less than decades means the malfeasance can continue. And worse, as an important editorial in Aviation Week explains, Boeing’s top brass shows no intention of changing their self-serving ways.

Most here know the broad outlines of the Boeing story. The company was founded in the early days of aviation, an industry built by inventors and engineers like Howard Hughes. To truncate a very long history, Boeing emerged a winner after a long period of industry consolidation. A company and industry-defining bet was the decision to bet on a new, untested concept: a large capacity, long-distance passenger plane, with only an order from Pan Am as a vote of confidence (important but no where new enough to assure the viability of the investment). But the 747 became an enormous success. It not only helped propel Boeing to its current dominant position but reshaped the industry by lowering the cost to passengers of long-haul travel, greatly expanding the market. Oddly, or perhaps in keeping with America’s warped priorities, Wikipedia’s extensive entry on Boeing makes nary a mention of the key role of the 747 to Boeing and commercial aviation. 1


Most readers also likely know of the key event that has brought Boeing to its current beleagured state, its 1997 acquisition of McDonnell Douglas. Despite Boeing being the larger company, McDonnell Douglas came out on top managerially. McDonnell Douglas was finance driven, not product driven, and quickly started remaking the company in its image. It moved the headquarters and key operations out of Seattle, in large measure to get rid of perceived to be too costly engineers. It became an outsourcing enthusiast, eventually including outsourcing parts to China. The results, starting with the 787, were not good. From a 2011 Reuters account:

The parked planes are 787-8 Dreamliners, the world’s first commercial aircraft with a body and wings made largely of lightweight carbon-composite materials instead of aluminum. Someday these sleek, fuel-efficient machines — already painted in the liveries of their airline customers — may change the face of air travel and plane-making.

But not today.

The program that produced these unfinished 787s is nearly three years behind schedule and, by some estimates, at least several billion dollars over budget. Dreamliner flight tests were halted in November after an electrical fire aboard a test plane….

About 45 miles away in south Seattle, members of Boeing’s work force gathered at a union hall for a monthly lodge meeting, a holiday party and a chance to lament the seismic shift in plane-making strategy they say the Dreamliner represents.

The 787 is not merely a historic feat of engineering. The program also marks Boeing’s departure from its own time-honored manufacturing practices.

Instead of drawing primarily from its traditional pool of aircraft engineers, mechanics and laborers that runs generations deep in the Puget Sound region around Seattle, Boeing leads an international team of suppliers and engineers from the United States, Japan, Italy, Australia, France and elsewhere, who make components that Boeing workers in the United States put together.
Advertisement

“Do you see the stupidity in that?” said James Williams, an imposing 43-year-old who has been employed by Boeing for 15 years, mostly working in factory safety.

Williams, whose father worked at Boeing for more than three decades, is just one of many in the company who blame the repeated Dreamliner delays on a splintered engineering strategy and a complex supply chain of about 50 partners…

Whatever the advantages, Boeing’s outsourcing is emblematic of corporate practices that have sent large chunks of U.S. industry overseas and to other states, battered communities and vaulted the U.S. jobless rate to nearly 10 percent, economists say.

Yet the biggest victim may be the culture that underpins the aerospace behemoth. Here in Boeing country, where children follow parents into the aviation business, outsourcing is plain heresy.

“It was like the family,” said Williams, whose wife, Sarah, and three children joined him for the holiday party. “Can you outsource Mom? Can you outsource Dad?”

While this story indicates that Boeing would bring a bit of its outsourced manufacture back in house, there would be no fundamental rethink, merely an effort to fine tune. And yours truly has strong suspicions as to why Boeing would not consider a more serious rollback of its troubled outsourcing strategy. It’s not as if this were due to competitive cost pressures (more on that soon). As one colleague pointed out, it was not as if Boeing’s big competitor, Airbus, was a lean and mean company (although aerocraft profits are to a degree a function of how many planes of a particular model you sell; there appear to be meaningful scale factors at that level). Not only does Airbus have to contend with an allegedly well-paid and hard to fire work force, but production of its components is divvied among countries in its consortium, creating a supply chain not optimized for cost. Yet Boeing acted as if it needed to squeeze on costs to compete with Airbus?

Upper management ego was probably a factor; as we see on an almost daily basis, big dogs double down rather than be seen as admitting error. But featly to Wall Street was likely an even bigger factor. I know executives in other industries who have said the case for their company to outsource was not strong. They could have achieved the same margins at lower risk by improving manufacturing processes, such as their implementation of just-in-time. But their stock was sure to rise if they started outsourcing.

To simplify the history for the purpose of getting to the choices Boeing faces now, another critical set of decisions involved the 737. It has been a widly successful model, the first aircraft ever to get over 10,000 orders after its third redesign, the so-called Next Generation. But it is also a 1967 design that Boeing has kept tweaking to keep up with market demands and competitive pressure. As a CNN story explains, by 2012, even with its considerable success, the 737 was already looking long in tooth in 2012 and Boeing was feeling the hot breath of the Airbus 320 on its neck. But rather than design a new plane, Boeing decided to wring more life out of the 737. The MCAS debacle came straight out of this choice. From CNN:

The Boeing 737 Max was announced in 2011, the fourth generation of the aircraft.

“Boeing needed to combat what Airbus were doing with the A320neo, a version of the plane with a new engine that was quite substantially more fuel efficient,” says Simons.

To do so, however, the company ran into a problem it had encountered before: the new, much bigger engines it wanted for the 737 Max wouldn’t fit under the plane’s low wings – an issue Airbus didn’t have, because the A320 was already a much taller plane than the 737.

The solution was to add some length to the front landing gear and mount the engines further forward and higher on the wings, giving them the clearance they needed.

But, as Boeing later found out in simulators, this altered the plane’s aerodynamics, making it tilt up dangerously in certain situations.

To counter the problem, the company devised a safety system called MCAS, which would immediately push the 737’s nose down if it tilted too high.

Because MCAS was designed to make the 737 Max fly just like previous 737s, and because Boeing believed that it would come into action only in extreme flying circumstances, it was kept almost secret.

Boeing decided against including it in the brief lesson that pilots already certified for previous 737s needed to take to fly the 737 Max.

There’s more to the “kept almost secret” part, like not including the existence of MCAS in pilot manuals and telling faithful 737 buyer Southwest Airlines what it wanted to hear, that pilots would not need additional simulator training to fly the MCAS. But you get the idea.

You would think after a disaster like that, Boeing would be humbled and stick to its knitting, as in worry about making better planes. But noes!



AirLive describes a new Boeing incident: A Virgin Atlantic Boeing 787-9 returned to London Heathrow with the Ram air turbine deployed. From the story. And remember, last week Lever News reported Airlines Filed 1,800 Reports Warning Regulators About Boeing’s 737 Max. And yes, sport fans, this was after the 737 Max was grounded for 20 months as Boeing had to ‘splain to regulators all over the world why its MCAS fixes were not another ticking time bomb.

One would think the flatlining of Boeing’s stock would focus the minds of its top management and board. But CEOs and their hangers-on often manage to get “Heads I win, tails you lose” pay deals, so it’s doubtful their comp has been dinged as much as it ought to be.

Two new stories look at how Boeing can pull itself out of its nosedive. A Financial Times account is fairly anodyne, framing its story around what happens to various Boeing dependents, like suppliers and long-standing customers that have tuned their operations around the Boeing product. What it does not contemplate is what happens if Boeing debacles get worse. The airline industry is correctly obsessed with safety. Customers will not fly if they think their plane might fall out of the sky. But the industry has very high barriers to entry, and no incumbent or aspirant who could meaningfully replace Boeing’s capacity in anything less than a decade even if customers rebelled. From the Financial Times:

At stake is not just Boeing’s standing as a leader in aviation. The company’s mis-steps have prompted some industry experts to ask if there has been a decisive shift of power towards Airbus in the duopoly that governs aerospace….

“It is absolutely critical that we have a strong Boeing and that we have a strong Airbus and that the two of them at least compete with each other, not just for orders, but also . . . in terms of technological developments,” says Michael O’Leary, chief executive of Ryanair, one of Boeing’s biggest customers.

That depends on Boeing turning things around. If it cannot, there would be consequences for the aerospace supply chain and for airline customers.

New entrants have tried to break into the industry but with mixed success. Comac, China’s state-backed aerospace champion whose first single-aisle C919 commercial flight took to the skies last year, has begun to emerge as the first real threat in decades….

When the C919 made its inaugural flight in 2023 it marked a breakthrough in China’s aims for technological self-sufficiency. But the aircraft is highly reliant on western suppliers for critical components, including communication and navigation systems, engines, landing gears, wheels and brakes…

But the Comac aircraft is not without problems, he [O’Leary] argues, calling it “a glorified A320”. O’Leary adds: “So the more aircraft Comac produces, you’re drawing off the same engine suppliers, the same avionics suppliers . . . it’s an A320 in all but name.”

Despite widespread scepticism that Comac can be a viable competitor anytime soon, technological development by China — including advancements in sectors including computer chips and electric vehicles — has caused some consternation in the west…

AerCap’s [Aengus] Kelly points to the enormous technological challenges that go with building aircraft and engines. He predicts it will take Comac “another 20-30 years to match what Boeing and Airbus currently do”.
.

Brazil’s Embraner is not seen as likely to be able to make up for a big fall in Boeing orders, not due to a lack of technical chops, but the cautionary example of Canada’s Bombadier, which nearly went bankrupt after trying to move into the big leagues.

Yet despite the widespread recognition of the importance to the airline industry and the US of Boeing turning itself around, an important op-ed in Aviation News explains that Boeing management has no intention of changing its grifting ways, and none of the few players that could pressure them look inclined to act. From Aviation News:

Can anything save Boeing from its management?…

The safety concerns and manufacturing errors plaguing the company’s jetliner unit are just part of the problem. The production ramp-up has been a series of disappointments that will only worsen as regulators and customers scrutinize manufacturing and inspection processes.

The company is also quickly losing market share. CEO Dave Calhoun’s November 2022 announcement that there would be no new Boeing jetliner this decade had a predictable result: a record 1,300 Airbus A321neo orders in 2023. Boeing will be very lucky to retain 40% of the market by decade’s end. Given relentless cost-cutting and the demographics of the engineering workforce, it will be quite difficult for the company to create a new jetliner in the 2030s.

The situation may be worse on the defense side. Billions of dollars have been lost due to poor execution and ill-advised fixed-price contracts—over $2 billion in 2022 alone…..

For years, Boeing management was accused of focusing on money rather than products, performance or people. Between 2014 and 2018, it gave away $53 billion in dividends and buybacks…

As 2023 ended, the company’s strategy department was abolished. Unit strategy functions were also reduced. The company no longer wants a plan for company-wide new technology development, new product development or, most crucial, restoring the links between the people who design and build aircraft and the people who manage the company. There are also no plans to promote technical people to senior management positions. Stephanie Pope’s recent appointment as chief operating officer means another finance person has been made Calhoun’s heir apparent.

The future, if it can be called that, is simply to run the company for cash—deliver legacy jets, try to make existing defense programs profitable, and resume converting cash flow into shareholder returns. Management may also try to sell off parts of the company—or perhaps all of it. The implications of this for the U.S. aerospace industry, defense industrial base and even the broader economy are potentially enormous.

In other words, Boeing management is liquidating the company. It’s such a huge player with a customer base that will find it hard to go anywhere that this will be a long and personally profitable ride. Shame for all those hangers on, though.

We described in 2005 in the Conference Board Review how the corporate fixation on short-term profits was resulting in dis-investment, which was a socially acceptable way to say liquidating. It has been masked in many cases by acquisitions, so the parent entity looks bigger even as its constituent parts are shrinking. Boeing is becoming a very big and consequential version of what happens when this practice continues unimpeded.

Oh, and maybe Tolstoy was not wrong. These looting managements are fundamentally similar and are no doubt happy with their lucre.

___

1 Due to the before Internet v. after Internet era, Lambert, who helpfully went looking, was unable to find an online version of the four-part (!!!!) New Yorker story on the birth of the 747. He did find some later stories on product competition among the then-majors:

https://www.newyorker.com/magazine/1982 ... he-company

The full download looks like the book derived from the article

https://www.scribd.com/document/92138009/Sporty-Game

Also on the DC-10, McDonnell-Douglas widebody

https://www.slideshare.net/MichaelRomega/dc10-72953842

Lambert notes” Precursor of 737 engineering and decision making?”

https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2024/01 ... alism.html
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Thu Feb 08, 2024 3:20 pm

Rob Urie: Imperialism, Lenin, and US Wars Abroad
Posted on February 8, 2024 by Yves Smith

Yves here. Rob Urie updates a tale foretold by Lenin, and Marx too: that capitalism leads to concentration and inequality. Financial capitalism and conquest (formal and by creating vassals) extend that process.

By Rob Urie, author of Zen Economics, artist, and musician who publishes The Journal of Belligerent Pontification on Substack

The growing sense that ‘the world’ is falling apart is more precisely the US working through the contortions and dislocations of late-stage capitalism. Following four plus decades of increasingly shrill exhortations that ‘markets’ were the base institution of capitalism, the Wall Street bailouts of 2008 – 2009 demonstrated that the Federal government of the US is the sponsor of much of the finance capitalism that now encircles the globe. The motive for this presence: to consolidate US power in the world. Anyone who imagines that doing so isn’t ‘political’ should study the history of IMF (International Monetary Fund) workouts.


Within the capitalist purview, finance is politically neutral, one possible path for economic development. Laid out in graphs below is that the growth of private debt (to GDP) has taken place at a particular point in capitalist development, one far away from the industrial roots of capitalist production. A stylized fact pertaining to this stage is economic concentration, with power ever more narrowly distributed ‘inside’ of capitalist economies. As income and wealth have concentrated, so has economic production. The US is now decades into the current epoch of monopoly capitalism.

The purpose of this essay is to develop social explanations of events as they unfold. If retired US military officers are correct (see here, here, here), the US lacks the munitions to win even one of the wars that it is currently engaged in. Moreover, its position resembles that of the Biden administration, where the current path is visible, but not articulated. The American strategy has been an ad hoc assemblage of explicit and stealth financing of arms sales from the American MIC to belligerents carefully assembled by the US to serve its imperial goals.


Image
Graph: while the Western evolution from industrial to financial capitalism is a mystery to capitalist economists, both Marx and Lenin not only predicted it, but explained the economic rationale for it. While public debt can be paid through sovereign money creation, individuals and corporations lack the legal authority to do so. And while much of this private debt (to GDP) consists of mortgages, asset seizure is the legal ‘right’ of most loans when debts go unpaid. This gives financial institutions great leverage over the lives of debtors. Additionally, financial institutions shift from being passive lenders to financial gamesmanship to consolidate their own power as these epochs unfold. Source: IMF.

To prevail militarily would mean rebuilding the industrial infrastructure that DC insiders have spent the last forty years jettisoning. The $60 billion that the Biden administration has been desperate to secure for Ukraine is more precisely to keep NATO’s loss to Russia from voters until after the 2024 election. Related, the 51-billion-euro war funding recently approved by the EU is a placeholder to keep the American, German, and French munitions manufacturers flush with cash to facilitate a permanent war against Russia. What success would look like in this scenario is the further concentration of Western economic production in ‘American’ hands, meaning oligarchs and corporate executives.


Image
Graph: as predicted by Lenin, American capitalism has become highly concentrated over time. Large US corporations (dark green area) have become larger, and industries more concentrated, since the 1930s. This concentration means less competition from weaker players, leaving large corporations firmly in control of Western political economy. Note that monopoly and oligopoly capitalism, the result of this concentration, bear no relationship to the competitive firms that Western economists claim as the basis of ‘market’ economies. Source: Booth School University of Chicago.

The answer to the great mystery of why the US launches, or otherwise engages in, wildly murderous and destructive wars no matter who, or which duopoly party, is in power is: war is the business of America. Some economies produce mangoes and kittens and some produce wars. The (military) Keynesian project that followed WWII in the US was intended to be a broadly distributive jobs program for returning veterans. However, in thoroughly predictable fashion, capitalist consolidation and concentration dictated that these firms would be ‘rationalized,’ meaning the canard of capitalist ‘efficiency’ deployed, to convert broad economic distribution into highly concentrated distribution.

In capitalist economics, monopoly is the rare instance where power is naturally concentrated (e.g. laid phone lines), and thus a role for government ‘interference’ in markets is warranted, if only rarely deployed. In contrast, Lenin perceived capitalism in terms of historical development, and not through ‘comparative statics’ based in Cartesian time. Thus, the great mystery of oligarchs and corporate executives substantially controlling Western political economy is framed as a problem of ‘money in politics.’ However, the movement of this consolidation from a weak state to a strong state has been a function of historical development, and not a static input that yields equivalent results irrespective of its place in history.


Image
Graph: restating the data in the top chart, it becomes obvious that 1) industry concentration has been rising in the US for the last century and 2) monopoly and oligopoly power now form the core of US capitalism. Using an intuitive example with the ACA (Obamacare), atomized individuals choose amongst products created by monopoly and oligopoly producers. In other words, ‘market signals’ only travel in one direction— downward. Further, the quantity and quality of the product delivered in exchange is determined only after the transaction has been completed. Such an economy only works in the presence of the capacity of individuals to negotiate as equals. The ACA is structured to assure that such a balance-of-power never arises. Source: University of Chicago.

This tendency towards consolidation increasingly makes large, concentrated, enterprises the enemy of small business, the alleged ‘lifeblood’ of Western capitalism. The ‘Golden Rule’ of capitalism, that s/he who owns the gold, rules, implicitly recognizes both the concentrated power that exists within capitalism, and its value as ‘political’ capital. Via the neoliberal ethos, politicians are self-interested economic actors. Their theater of operation is government ‘management’ of capital, e.g. the 2008 – 2009 Wall Street bailouts. Politicians see the vast fortunes that they provide ‘their’ donors with, and act to put as much of that as they can into their own pockets.


Image
Chart: in the 1960s, Washington, DC was one of the poorest cities in the US. Seventy years, and one neoliberal coup, later DC and environs are a playground for the rich. Moreover, ‘public service’ has become code for creating self-enriching programs nominally in the public interest, as well as the revolving door between government and business. Of note is that Democrats have been openly feeding at this trough right next to Republicans. While median wealth in the US in 2022 was $192,900, former House Speaker Nancy Pelosi has squirreled away $110,000,000 through insider trading and shaking down campaign contributors. Source: opensecrets.org.

Any history of the US relationship with Russia that looks back farther than February 24, 2022, the start of Russia’s SMO (Special Military Operation), finds three decades of the Russians politely asking the US not to surround it with NATO forces as the US continued to do so. Likewise, the US-sponsored genocide currently unfolding in Gaza begs the question of where the Palestinians who are being exiled will go? Doesn’t the US support landless people who are being exterminated by a ruthless tyrant? (No). In fact, Israel is doing the bidding of the Biden administration in Gaza as DC insiders are still ranting about the Iranian Revolution (1979). Again, history, rather than theory, has bearing.

Additionally, the question of why the US has historically acted to crush budding democracies is answered with: American capitalists 1) need customers and 2) don’t want competitors. Consider: the historical trajectory of the last century of capitalism has been toward the consolidation and concentration of economic production in fewer and fewer hands. Capitalists could have been ‘kind’ and saved their American competitors from ruin, but profit maximization / rent extraction led them to conclude otherwise. Why would national competitors look any more kindly upon international competitors? They wouldn’t. Hence concentration is both ‘internal’ and ‘external’ to national economies.

The American refusal to simply exist amongst other nations in a multipolar world, but instead needing to dominate them, finds analog in this consolidation and concentration of American industry (graphs above). In key sectors, industry concentration creates economies of scale and market power that in turn produce high barriers to entry for competitors. The phrase ‘go big or go home’ captures the strategy while excluding its motivating logic. As this process has unfolded historically, ‘American’ industry has become increasingly concentrated, with very high (95%) concentration at present. This reframes ‘income inequality’ away from moral chide (‘greed’) to make it an effect of economic concentration


Image
Graph: coincident with industrial concentration has been the concentration of incomes and wealth in fewer and fewer hands. Illustrated is that the poorer 80% of the US receives only a tiny fraction of the income earned by the rich. This distribution is likewise a function of historical development, and not ‘merit.’ The incomes and wealth that accrue to oligarchs and corporate executives are a function of market power, not equitable distribution. In this history, incomes and wealth have concentrated as market power has. ‘Merit’ is misdirection intended to explain away this power as a function of nature rather than the economic dysfunction of late-stage capitalism. Source: inequality.org.

The way that consolidation and concentration work is that economies of scale in some industries (e.g. manufacturing, finance) lead to price competition that is ruinous for smaller players who lack these economies. This leads to them either being bought out by their competitors, or they go out of business. And viola, consolidation and concentration are the result. To be clear, this is due to market structure in applicable industries, not to the moral failing of capitalists. In the US, institutional economists imagined that these efficiencies would be shared with ‘consumers.’ Why would they think this? Earning monopoly and oligopoly rents are the goal of concentration.

With the current ‘leadership’ of the US launching conflicts with Russia, Hamas (Israel), Lebanon, and Iran, one could be forgiven for imagining that it has the capability to prevail militarily. But again, according to retired military (links above), the US lacks the munitions and materiel to prevail against even one of these ‘enemies.’ By reports, Donald Trump had planned to launch a war against Iran until he was told by his military advisors that the US would quickly lose such a conflict. Should Biden attack Iran, it could well spell the end of the US. Once a tipping point is reached, the US should expect blowback for the last 150 years of imperial predation.

It was telling that Joe Biden, as he was flailing about for talking points to sell his war against Russia, started claiming an economic benefit from the US proxy war against Russia. George W. Bush, Biden’s spirit-guide, also claimed an economic benefit after no WMDs were found in Iraq during his disastrous war there. In economic terms, both were repeating the ‘broken windows fallacy,’ the notion that economic destruction that will be replaced provides an economic benefit. While this may be true of GDP calculations that don’t net economic losses from new spending, it is utterly grotesque in human terms as a theory of how the world ‘works.’

The fallacy is the claim that ‘the economy’ benefits when a window is broken because it will be replaced. GDP rises when the replacement glass is produced, ergo there is an economic benefit to breaking windows. Of course, what wasn’t done here was to deduct the value of the window that was broken from the revenue received for the new glass. Note: the act of paying for the new glass implies that the old glass had economic value before it was broken, else why replace it? It provided the same ‘utility’ as the new glass. In human time / space, wars always and everywhere cost more than they produce in terms of economic benefit.

What Biden doesn’t address with respect to the windows he is breaking is the resulting distribution of payments and costs. The MIC gets rich from war production The rest of us, not so much. So, there is one group, the MIC, that loves war because it gets rich from it. But the rest of humanity is rendered dead, disabled and / or destroyed by it. With the broken windows fallacy, Biden is telling the MIC that it will benefit from the destruction of Ukraine and Gaza. But as far as the net benefit to humanity from war goes, it has a giant minus sign in front of it. So, Biden is making the imperialist argument from the perspective of those in the US for whom death and destruction are a business.

What Western economists choose not to address with respect to capitalism is economic distribution. Via ongoing concentration across and within industries, industrial concentration is a partial explanation for the recent re-concentration of incomes and wealth. The HBO series Succession features a wealthy family that spends its days replicating the court intrigue of yesteryear as it produces nothing of social value. That they are rich is a function of financial gamesmanship rather than besting their competitors in the production of goods and services. ‘Merit’ in this case is skill at financial manipulation and court intrigue, rather than making better goods at a lower price.

Liberals, the American left, and yours truly, perceive current US actions with respect to the Israelis in Gaza to be ‘fascist,’ in the sense of committing a racist genocide against the Palestinians. However, the Israelis plan an economic benefit from exiling Palestinians from Israel. They want the land for additional Israeli settlements, and possibly oil and gas extraction from the sea just off the coast of Gaza. The Americans want business for the MIC, a place to land and refuel fighter jets, control of the wider Middle East, and continued American domination of the world.

Looking back, the Americans managed to sell WWII as a moral battle of good Americans defeating evil Nazis. In fact, it was the Soviets, now ‘Russians,’ who defeated the Nazis. And the Americans are invited to explain how some imperial powers are good and others evil when they are all imperialistic? It was all the way back in the 1930s when former US General Smedley Butler proclaimed the role of the US military to be as a ‘gangster for capitalism.’ The US military exists to make the world safe for the few industrialists, financiers, and resource extractors who now constitute the American ruling class.

That the political establishment in the US appears comfortable with Biden’s provocations with respect to Russia and Israel has a lot to do with it being the beneficiary. In 1968, Washington, DC was one of the poorest cities in the US. In 2024, DC and environs are the richest. Now recall the graphs above that illustrate the historical process of industry and wealth concentration in the US. In 1968, industry concentration was lower, and so were house prices in DC. In 2024, industry concentration is higher, as are the concentrations of income and wealth. Lenin might have it that neoliberalism represented the evolution from industrial to finance capitalism.

In the American / capitalist frame, this evolution reflects the aggregated personal choices of three-hundred and thirty-million Americans, and was therefore impossible to predict. But both Marx and Lenin predicted it just fine. Through its internal dynamics, capitalist competition leads to consolidation, and with it, concentration. The abandonment of populist / progressive anti-trust enforcement is likewise treated as a mystery. However, as consolidation proceeds, power accrues to the remaining industrialists. Once finance enters the mix, the process of consolidation moves into warp speed. A central fact of the last four decades has been pirate capitalism, the monetization of pieces of companies as assets are being stripped.


Image
Graph: NAFTA was claimed to bring Mexico into the top tier of capitalist countries. But the reality is quite different. From the day that NAFTA was implemented, the rate of growth of Mexican GDP began to decline. This, as FDI (foreign direct investment) rose and millions of Mexicans saw their livelihoods destroyed, leading to their abandonment of traditional ways of living. Those angered by Donald Trump’s xenophobia need to take a hard look in the mirror. Bill Clinton’s policies (e.g. NAFTA) produced the economic refugees from Mexico that Trump was able to exploit politically. Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve.

With Mexico’s experience with NAFTA as a close and intuitive example, after it was passed, American agricultural products were dumped in Mexico, thereby driving prices below the costs of production for the indigenous peasants of Mexico. The livelihoods of millions of peasants were destroyed, ‘freeing’ them to go to work in the maquiladoras that line the US-Mexico border for dollars a day, or to flee north to the US in search of a wage. People who had been self-sufficient were made dependent on food imports, and to work in the cash-economy controlled by multinational corporations.

In either nominal or inflation adjusted terms, US-based multinational corporations have profited handsomely from NAFTA, while those who were told they would benefit have had their lives destroyed by it (see here, here, here, here).

“As for Mexico’s interest in this bilateral relationship, it can be summarized in two facts: about 80% of Mexico’s exports go to the U.S., while 50% of the accumulated foreign direct investment received between 2000 and 2011 comes from the U.S. Moreover, NAFTA has been the fundamental anchor for reforms that make Mexico a more modern economy and open society.” Mauro Guillen, UPENN.

The ‘reforms that make Mexico a more modern economy and open society’ is reference to the imagined ‘liberalizing effects’ of imperialism. With the history of NAFTA in hand, it was a neo-colonial pact whereby so-called ‘reforms’ in Mexico facilitated the extraction of wealth by connected Americans. The claim of benefits to Mexico and Mexicans doesn’t even work as an average, because the growth rate of Mexico’s GDP has fallen since NAFTA was implemented. Certainly, some Mexicans have benefited. They would be the colonial administrators for the Americans plus a few random capitalists. Consider, the same Joe Biden that supported NAFTA as he slandered the Mexican peasants who fled to the US as a consequence of it, is now ‘helping’ the Ukrainians.

While readers may quibble with some of the characterizations in this piece, the broad outline fits the facts of ‘our’ conundrum. As the most advanced capitalist economy in the world, the US is farthest down the path of its final stage. ‘The world’ has been here before— in the run-up to WWI. V.I. Lenin wrote ‘Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism, during this run-up. Had it not been for the New Deal, the fate of the US would have been left in the hands of capital. The only publicly acknowledged ‘fascist coup’ attempted in the US, the ‘Business Plot’ of 1933 revealed by General (Smedley) Butler, was carried out by Wall Street financiers

With no time to relearn old lessons, the American political leadership has gone completely off the rails by starting wars that it can’t win. Implied is a winner-take-all resolution whereby imagined competitors will be absorbed into the winner. This was the American plan for Russia before the Russians won the war in Ukraine. While you and I, dear readers, never voted for this program, the American ruling class did. And if you imagine this ruling class to be intelligent and world-wise, think again. While things fall apart for us, the stock market is at a record high.

Takeaways: over the last century, capital has consolidated in the manner, and to the extent, predicted by both Marx and Lenin. The motivation for this consolidation is intrinsic to capitalism. It therefore doesn’t comport with the liberal / American left concern with class struggle around the residual of industrial capitalism. Finance capital, the fluid of late-stage capitalism, differs fundamentally from its industrial forebear via its place in the evolutionary process of capitalism. Attacking the old form distracts from effectively addressing its evolutionary product.

https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2024/02 ... broad.html
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Thu Apr 04, 2024 3:21 pm

Image
Bank of England. (Photo: Flickr/Alexander Johmann)

Central bank independence as class war strategy
By John Clarke (Posted Apr 04, 2024)

Originally published: Counterfire on March 27, 2024 (more by Counterfire) |

Kristalina Georgieva, Managing Director of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), recently offered up a blog post on the need to ‘strengthen central bank independence to protect the world economy.’ In it, she nervously urges the preservation of this key neoliberal strategy in the face of economic instability and the threat of political pressure.

Georgieva is bothered that:

…central bankers today face many challenges to their independence. Calls are growing for interest-rate cuts, even if premature, and are likely to intensify as half the world’s population votes this year. Risks of political interference in banks’ decision making and personnel appointments are rising. Governments and central bankers must resist these pressures.

It is presumably with complete seriousness that Georgieva urges her readers to ‘consider what independent central banks have achieved in recent years.’ She goes on to set out a list of everything central banks have done to maintain a level of stability for global capitalism which, as far as she is concerned, is synonymous with the wellbeing of working-class populations.

Monetary policy
According to Georgieva, during the pandemic, central bankers ensured an ‘aggressive monetary easing that helped prevent a global financial meltdown and speed recovery.’ However, as ‘the focus shifted to restoring price stability, central bankers appropriately tightened monetary policy—albeit on different timelines. Their response helped to keep inflation expectations anchored in most countries even as price increases reached multi-decade highs.’

Based on the questionable assumption that interest-rate policies have calmed inflation and brought it under control, Georgieva goes on to assert that ‘their success thus far has largely been because of the independence and credibility that many central banks have built up in recent decades.’ She even suggests that the relatively short-lived nature of runaway inflation in the recent period, as opposed to the more severe experience of the 1970s, is attributable to central bank independence.

Georgieva is anxious to dispel any confused ideas that independence might be taken to mean a lack of accountability. She grandly pronounces that ‘to wield enormous power in democratic societies, trust is key. Central banks must earn that trust every day—through strong governance, transparency, and accountability, and delivering on core responsibilities.’

At the heart of this earned trust is ensuring that ‘monetary policy is predictable and based on achieving mandated long-term goals, rather than short-term political gains. It starts with a clear legislative mandate that sets price stability as the main objective.’ She warns any weak sentimentalists who might put employment ‘on the same pedestal’ as price stability that they will only fail in their aim if they dare to interfere with the vital work of the central bankers.

Elected governments should stay out of the way of their central banks, and avoid being so fiscally reckless that effective monetary policy becomes more difficult. ‘When central banks and governments each play their roles, we have seen better control of inflation, better outcomes in growth and employment, and lower financial stability risks.’

Far from simply throwing in comments from the sidelines, however, the ‘IMF is here to help policymakers face these challenges.’ The agency can offer ‘technical assistance to members working to improve governance and legal frameworks’ and is always ready to ‘make independence an explicit pillar in some Fund-supported financing programs, agreeing with members on actions to measure and achieve it.’

Georgieva concludes her message with an appeal to ‘preserve and strengthen central banks to win the fight against inflation today and foster economic stability and growth for years to come’ because ‘this will benefit everyone.’ In this situation, with ‘such high stakes, we must preserve and strengthen central bank independence.’

American post-Keynesian economist Thomas Palley has argued that ‘central bank independence is a product of neoliberal economics and aims to advance and institutionalize neoliberal interests.’ The major shift towards it ‘occurred in the late 1980s and 1990s, a period which witnessed the cementing of neoliberal political and economic hegemony.’

Palley suggests that ‘central bank independence can be thought as a quasi-outsourcing of interest-rate policy.’ As such, ‘it sides with the economic interests of capital against those of labor.’ Its effectiveness as a strategy is to create the illusion that monetary policy is a purely technical matter that elected governments should leave to technocrats. While governments can and do play their own major role in imposing austerity agendas, the unaccountable central bank is insulated from popular discontent and political pressure and, as such, is an effective means of imposing class-war policies.

The dogged insistence by the IMF and the central banks that the interest rate increases of the last period have been prudent measures that have successfully curbed inflation, the nature of the sudden price instability calls this into question, as noted by a range of commentators. Writing in UnHerd, Thomas Fazi addresses the Bank of England specifically, pointing out that ‘officially, the Bank’s actions are aimed at curbing inflation. But this approach would only make sense if the current inflation were being driven by excess demand.’

It has been well established that price rises were driven by ‘supply shocks’ following the pandemic and that this was compounded by opportunistic profiteering in some commodity sectors. All talk of a ‘wage-price spiral’ was simply not rooted in any honest assessment of the situation. In reality, the actions of the central banks very deliberately sought to weaken the capacity of workers to compensate for a decline in real wages.

The response of the central banks to the cost-of-living crisis can more accurately be viewed as a pre-emptive strike. Inflationary pressure did indeed prompt rising levels of working-class militancy in a number of countries. The fear of the central bankers and the class whose interests they represent was that this trend might reach levels that could threaten the greatly strengthened position they had achieved during the neoliberal decades. The whole central bank offensive, then, was primarily driven by a desire to undermine ‘a potential rise in labour bargaining power.’

Agile class war
It is highly significant that the IMF’s Managing Director weighs in on the question of central bank independence at this juncture. It is part of the Fund’s focus on ‘refining and adapting the institution’s core activities to support member countries as they face challenges posed by ongoing transitions in the global economy.’

Georgieva and her colleagues are well aware that global capitalism is far less stable than it was in the period before the financial crisis of 2008. In this situation, the IMF plays a leading role in developing a class-war strategy based on ‘agility, integration, and member focus.’ This would allow for a major effort to suppress wages, impose austerity and boost profitability, while keeping a close eye on economic danger signals so as make abrupt turns towards temporary or localised stimulatory measures in order to avert uncontrolled crises.

In this regard, the independent central bank, as a key achievement of the neoliberal decades, is an indispensable tool. Significantly walled off from political pressure and linked closely to financial capital, the central bank has a particularly important and ruthless role to play.

Working-class people across the world, however, are unlikely to be convinced by the IMF’s insistence that this harsh medicine is being forced upon them in the common interest. Georgieva’s goals of stability and growth will mean reduced living standards and intensified exploitation. However, this may in turn reveal that the independent central banks are simply not insulated enough to escape the anger and resistance that their measures unleash.

https://mronline.org/2024/04/04/central ... -strategy/
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

User avatar
blindpig
Posts: 10772
Joined: Fri Jul 14, 2017 5:44 pm
Location: Turtle Island
Contact:

Re: The crisis of bourgeois economics

Post by blindpig » Mon Apr 08, 2024 2:17 pm

No Exit: Western Imperialism, Capitalism, and Industrialization
Posted on April 8, 2024 by Yves Smith

Yves here. Keep in mind that a big reason that economists, alone among social scientists, got a seat at the policy table, was concern about the way Russia managed to industrialize within a generation, something no bourgeois/market economy had achieved. The fear was that a command and control system could indeed outproduce a free enterprise economy, hence the need for the tender stewardship of experts to make sure those Commies didn’t outdo private capital. In other words, indirectly supporting Rob Urie’s thesis, the measure of success of both systems was their productive output. Until the US went hog wild for offshoring, that meant the level and efficiency of industrialization.

By Robert Urie, author of Zen Economics, artist, and musician who publishes The Journal of Belligerent Pontification on Substack

In the US, within the context of a never-ending Cold War, ideology is put forward as the dividing line between nations and peoples. As is the case with religion, social practices that are claimed to be radically different, or even oppositional, share most of their central characteristics between them. In terms of political economy, the major ideologies of fascism, capitalism, and communism have long been claimed to be oppositional— and they often have been militarily by way of competing economic interests, as each reflected different strategies for industrializing.

American claims against Soviet economic development in the twentieth century were over the form of industrialization, not the fact of it. Like ‘science,’ the fact of industrialization has long been considered ideologically neutral, even as its particular forms were considered antithetical, even irreconcilable. However, the purpose of this piece isn’t to reconcile competing ideologies, but rather to look through to the facts which industrialization imposes. While V.I. Lenin laid imperialism at the feet of capitalism, this piece argues that industrialization sets in motion a global contest for industrial inputs, and with it, political violence.

Image
Graph: while apples-to-apples GDP comparisons between countries can be complicated by currency fluctuations and inflation rates, this graph of China’s versus the US’s GDP (in PPP terms) is generally representative of the relationship, irrespective of these complications. After trailing US GDP for decades, China moved ahead of the US during the Great Recession. Given that ‘economic competition’ is the US’s stated rationale for war with Russia and China, the Great Recession appears to have spelled the end of American economic hegemony. Now ‘we’ get war. Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve.

The world’s best living economist, Michael Hudson, whose focus of inquiry has long been Western imperialism, has in recent years, and following from Lenin, devoted significant effort to distinguishing financial capitalism from its industrial predecessor. Supporting his thesis has been the fact that the most capitalist nation on earth, the US, has also been the most aggressively imperialistic. However, with China having now industrialized while still claiming ideological difference with the West, the global race to secure industrial inputs threatens to reignite global imperialist wars.

This isn’t to argue that China’s industrialization is in-and-of-itself motivating renewed imperial tensions. It is to argue that by way of the industrial process, competition for industrial inputs is doing so. While Americans respond with patriotic fervor to misleading nonsense about ‘freedom versus tyranny,’ industrial production provides the material basis for conflict between industrialized nations. Before age, isolation, and intellectual brittleness melted their brains, US officials clearly stated that the US motive for war with Russia was the threat that the Nord Stream LNG pipelines from Russia to Germany posed to ‘American’ interests.

To understand the conundrum from the American perspective, there is no space between the views of Joe Biden and Donald Trump regarding the US ‘right’ to seize industrial resources from sovereign nations. Mr. Trump has said so explicitly on multiple occasions. Mr. Biden defers to the Cold War canard of ‘freedom versus tyranny’ to claim a moral basis for his Hitlerian moves to light the world on fire. But the US also has a material basis for this conflict in the political control that is bought through the control of industrial inputs.

Since the mid-nineteenth century, industrialization has taken place in fits and starts around the world. Oddly (not), different ideological forms of political economy, e.g. communism, capitalism, fascism, didn’t challenge the logic of industrialization. For instance, amongst the participants in WWI, several were early to industrialize (US, Britain) and several were later to industrialize (Germany, Russia). The emergence of communism in 1917, with the Bolshevik Revolution, challenged capitalist economic organization, but not the imperative to industrialize.

That this imperative both preceded and followed WWI is hardly an accident. WWI was the first industrial war. Machine guns mowed down soldiers by the tens of thousands. Aerial bombardment facilitated the distribution of chemical and biological weapons. Monstrous machines were pitted against one another in scenes reminiscent or earlier portrayals of hell. For any nation that wanted to launch a war, or just protect itself from the imperial ambitions of others, industrialization was imperative.

Capitalist explainers tend to focus on the ‘stuff’ of industrial production, consumer goods and labor-saving devices (capital). Capitalist economists (aka ‘economists’) begin their explanations of capitalism with either imagined or real human wants (‘demand’), or sui generis economic production (‘supply’). But why would capitalists and communists both rely on the methods of industry even as they derided the competing ideological forms of social organization imagined to circumscribe it? Again, ideological difference was reflected in the form of social organization around industrialization, and not its material facts.

The Western critique of communist industrialization centered on the relative inefficiency of the communist form of industry (state direction), not on the shared imperative to industrialize. But the value of industrial output is socially determined. Capitalists long focused on creating consumer societies while the communists educated their people and provided healthcare. One can debate the merits of either vision, but both used industry as a central method to realize it.

In a broad sense, industrialization represents a path to generating certain types of wealth. Resources are gathered, and through the industrial process, are transformed into ‘wealth.’ Theories were developed to explain why certain types of wealth (‘capital’) are necessary to create other types of wealth (e.g. consumer goods). Institutional relationships were created through the industrialization process. In this way, industrial inputs aren’t ‘capitalist’ in the sense of being universally distributed. They exist in some geographic locations and not in others.

Contemporary Western economics places industrial dependencies in markets, ignoring the long history of imperialist wars to secure industrial inputs. WWI was the prime example of this tendency. Nations battled one another to control ‘wealth,’ including the industrial inputs that kept them in the fight. A later example from WWII illustrates this tendency. Japan entered WWII with an industrial economy but no secure supply of oil to keep it running. Understanding this, the Americans set up a naval blockade in the Pacific to prevent oil-laden ships from delivering oil to Japan. The Japanese faced the choice of shutting down their war machine or trying to end the naval blockade by bombing Pearl Harbor. They chose the latter.

This slice of history was brought into the present when the US purposely and significantly deindustrialized over the last half century. While this isn’t evident in the dollar value of US industrial output, it is evident in what types of industrial goods are being made, and the greatly shrunken level of manufacturing employment (graph below). The US is also currently engaged in two hot wars (Ukraine, Israel), and just launched a third (by letting Israel bomb the Iranian consulate in Damascus, Syria). Irrespective of differences in their forms of social organization, Chinese, German, and American industries all need resources that they don’t control.

In theory China has a different form of political economy (‘communist’) than the US (‘capitalist’). And it certainly seems (so far) to have avoided some of the pitfalls of financial capitalism via its state-banking system. With V. I. Lenin’s claim of the relationship of late-stage capitalism to imperialism in mind, will China respond differently (than the US) to being cut out of industrial resources through Western militarism? In other words, were the US to conduct a regime change operation in a nation that Chinese industry is dependent upon for industrial inputs, will China act militarily to regain control of the needed resources?

In more generic terms, will the revival of crude capitalist imperialism by the Biden administration result in a global race by nations to 1) militarize, in order 2) to secure industrial inputs? As discussed below, Europe has little choice but to do these or perish. The US ended relative energy security for Europe when it blew up the Nord Stream pipelines. Americans who question how reliable Russian LNG (liquified natural gas) really was need to take a hard look in the mirror. The Nord Stream pipelines were destroyed without a Plan B by the Americans, the people who blew it up. Whereas the Russians 1) had a plan and 2) the infrastructure to bring it to fruition, the Americans have a ten-year time frame for securing LNG deliveries to Europe.

Image
Graph: the Biden administration’s much- touted revival of US manufacturing has gotten manufacturing employment in the US back to where it was before the Covid-19 epidemic began in 2020. It still remains far below levels prior to 2001. Given that ‘economic competitiveness’ is the rationale for the US war against Russia in Ukraine, Mr. Biden is now in theory ‘trying’ to get back the jobs that his support for NAFTA in the early – mid 1990s, eliminated. Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve.

The base question here: is industry possible without imperialism? The decision of the US to deindustrialize, or more precisely, to outsource some industrial production, complicates assessments. As the US deindustrialized from the 1980s to the Great Recession, but particularly from the moment that China was elevated within the WTO (2001), the Americans became increasingly predisposed to a benign view of industrial competition. Now, having woken up from this imperial slumber, the US 1) lacks to ability to manufacture the weapons it will need 2) to fight the wars that it has already started.

This isn’t to overstate the case. The bipartisan George W. Bush-era war against Iraq was likely the least strategically coherent, most murderous, imperial adventure in post-WWII history. The list of nations destined for US regime change operations obtained by retired US General Wesley Clark in 2003 indicated no diminution in American blood-lust or imperial ambitions. The particular idiocy of the present is that the US gave away the industrial base that it now needs to pursue its renewed imperial ambitions.

Prior to the start of Russia’s SMO (Special Military Operation, now war) in Ukraine, developed Europe was buying LNG (liquified natural gas) from Russia at a discounted price. European industry benefitted from this arrangement because the discounted price raised profits. The arrangement ultimately gave Russia substantial political control over Europe because the withdrawal of Russian LNG would remove an instantiated source and would force European industry to pay a market price for LNG.

The destruction of the Nord Stream pipelines proceeded without the requisite planning needed to avoid an economic catastrophe for Europe. The American ‘plan,’ if it can be called that, is to spend several billion dollars over the next decade to build the infrastructure needed to deliver LNG produced by US based producers to Europe at twice or more the price that it had been paying to Russia. This price difference will render energy-intensive industries in Europe economically unviable, and slash profits for the industries that remain by the amount of the difference between the price of the ‘American’ LNG and the discounted price charged by the Russians.


Image
Graph: the term ‘greedflation’ is the case where corporate power has allowed corporations to unilaterally raise prices, thereby raising their profits. In capitalist economics, competition and regulation are supposed to prevent this. In fact, regulators long ago abandoned placing limits on corporate power, trusting— against history and economic logic, that ‘markets’ would prevent the accrual of market power. While the Biden administration has revived some anti-trust activity, its economic policies continue to favor economic consolidation in the hands of the oligarchs. Source; St. Louis Federal Reserve.

The question for which a satisfactory answer has yet to be given is why Europe went along with the American project in Ukraine? The ‘East versus West’ coalitions formed from it feature a cooperative East versus a vicious, petty, and tired West. The political misleaderships of Europe may be acceding to US plans to control the volume and price of energy inputs into European industry in the near-term, but doing so in the longer term will mean a severe decline for European industry. Moreover, simple geography argues against the success of the American plan. By geography alone, Russian LNG is the ‘efficient’ choice to transport.

Having jettisoned its basic industries, the US has no coherent plan to rebuild its own industrial base. The Biden administration came into office promising that its plan to build out EVs (electric vehicles) would jump start a global effort to solve mounting environmental woes. But its plan wasn’t to build EVs. The plan was to propose tax incentives for ‘green’ companies to build EVs. It was quickly determined that without building out the infrastructure needed to support the use of EVs, that few people— including auto manufacturers and electric utility executives, were on board with the build out. Rather than quickly moving to build the necessary infrastructure, the Biden administration simply backed away from its EV effort.

With the US currently engaged in two-plus wars, with no realistic way of manufacturing the weapons and materiel to fight them, and having primary responsibility for most of the environmental woes now accumulating, and no social interest in realistically addressing them, the future looks bleak. However, the West exists on the same planet as the collective East. Much like industries that lack industrial resources, producing toxic environmental effects on a shared planet is untenable in the longer term. Both suggest future geopolitical conflict.

Economist Michael Hudson, following from V.I. Lenin, has long argued that financial capitalism is a burden imposed on industrial capitalism via rent extraction and imperialism. While agreeing with Hudson on the point regarding financial capitalism, industrial capitalism produces its own burdens. Chinese officials have spent the last forty years scouring the earth to secure the inputs (resources) needed for Chinese industrial production. During this time the Americans have launched massively destructive wars in Nicaragua, El Salvador, Guatemala, Serbia, Iraq, Afghanistan, Libya, Yemen, Syria, and now Russia, Gaza, and Iran.

The question then is whether imperialism is idiosyncratic, or a function of industrialization and / or capitalism? Lenin’s argument depends in part on his theory of the genesis of state under capitalism. In this theory (following from Marx), the state exists to serve the interests of powerful capitalists. However, the nominally communist Chinese state promotes the interests of ‘Chinese’ industries through locating and negotiating for industrial inputs under the theory that doing so benefits the state via an integrated theory of the state (graph below).

A historical difference between this (implied) Chinese view and the view in capitalist states that private ownership and control of industry is efficient, is that the latter (US) relies on the state to launch imperial wars and squeeze international competitors using state power. For instance, blowing up the Nord Stream pipeline produced no conceivable benefit for the American people and put us in direct conflict with a nuclear armed power (Russia).

The Western ‘we’ involved in doing so is an abstraction. US state actions to support large-scale oil and gas producers (e.g. Chevron, ExxonMobil) miss that the concern isn’t reciprocal— the people who run these companies see Americans as prey, cannon fodder, and an annoyance, not fellow travelers. ‘American’ producers of LNG have destroyed aquifers across the nation with fracking waste. And the methane leaking from current and retired gas wells greatly increases US responsibility for climate change.

While American officials appear to be finally seeing some of the economic consequences of the neoliberal epoch, there appears to be little understanding of how these consequences actually came about. This is almost certainly because the same officials charged with seeing the consequences in the present didn’t anticipate them when they were proposing the policies that produced them. Additionally, class relation in the West have it that rich Westerners benefit from policies that harm the rest of us. Corporate profits rise in proportion to the environmental harms that rich Americans unload on the rest of us.

Image
Graph: the growth of wealth in China in recent decades has largely been a function of growth in private wealth. The richest ten percent in China own nearly as much of the national wealth as in the US. A central difference is that the rich in China don’t control the Chinese government (yet), like they do in the US. Will the Chinese government stand idly by if foreign imperialists (US) threaten this private wealth through resource imperialism? And given China’s foresight in securing contracts for industrial inputs, how will it react when the US moves to take these resources (think: Iraq 2003)? Source: Stanford University.

While Wall Street may be the most powerful cheerleader for gratuitous slaughter in the world today, bringing it to heel would likely do little to reduce the imperialist impulse that is currently driving US wars abroad. In capitalist terms, financialization can be understood as a method of transferring wealth from the people that created it to its newly minted owners via economic rent extraction and financial gamesmanship. The question then: is this also the purpose of China’s state-banking system? In other words, did China’s new ownership class create the wealth that it owns, or did financial gamesmanship simply place this ownership in its hands?

As with much in life, the answers are likely 1) partially and 2) yes, respectively. As metaphor, years ago yours truly was able to get unsecured ‘inside’ funding at a rate of one-quarter of one-percent at a time when credit card borrowers were paying 19.99%. The difference was proximity to the dealer desks on Wall Street. Given that both loan types (credit cards and the inside rate) were unsecured, the risks to the lenders were similar. Absent the proximity to power, the rates should have been the same. In this sense, financial capitalism is a way to make the rich and powerful, richer and more powerful. In this example, the money saved in interest charges (19.99 – 0.25 = 19.74%) represents a transfer of wealth to the rich (I didn’t keep the difference, it was passed along).

The American rhetorical ‘pivot’ from markets to war began about when China’s GDP eclipsed that of the US during the Great Recession (top graph above). In fact, without China’s massive fiscal expansion while the US and EU were in neoliberal-inspired austerity (2010 – 2015), ‘the West’ never would have recovered. And while American wars tend to be explained in geostrategic terms, both World Wars featured races to control industrial inputs to support the burgeoning industrialization of the epoch.

Here’s the problem: given the advent of industrial warfare, any nation that doesn’t want to be invaded and controlled by other nations has no choice but to industrialize. This truth promoted both aggressive and defensive industrialization. Those bent on world domination (US, Brits, Nazis), saw industrialization as a race to control the resources that serve as industrial inputs. And the nations that can shove their environmental harms onto others most effectively see a benefit in terms of national product / profits.

The conclusion here has yet to be written. Unlike the US, China hasn’t engaged in military conquest to secure industrial inputs in modern history. Looking forward, possibly it will and possibly it won’t. There are particulars, like the US existing between two vast oceans, that may well have led its political ‘leaders’ to develop skewed assessments of the potential risks and rewards of overseas military action. And US hatred of Russia is both racist (anti-Slav) and a residual of the imperial ambitions of the American ruling class in the lead up to WWI.

The goal here isn’t to charge China, or any other nation, with actions that it has not taken. It is to argue that the circumstances that might lead it to do so are rapidly accumulating. The material basis of this conflict is the resources that serve as industrial inputs. As ‘the East’ has reacted to American imperial ambitions with Russia’s SMO, now war, against NATO in Ukraine, the US is dangerously flailing about. So, to the point made above, with little to no interest in engaging in imperialist conflagrations, will the other nations of the world respond to American imperialism abroad militarily? Would doing so make them imperialist? Is this a distinction without a difference?

https://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2024/04 ... ation.html

The author ain't no Marxist, there's a lot more to imperialism than it's sharp end, war.

******

About competition
No. 4/92.IV.2024

At first, the most superficial glance, competition is a struggle between people for something valuable, for access to some important living conditions and resources.

In any case, competition is a confrontation between people. What is the basis of this opposition? First of all, some kind of interest , albeit appearing in the consciousness of the average person in a more subjective form of desire, thirst for possession or consumption.

Let's take an example. Let's say Ivan saved up money to buy a car. Ivan turned into a participant in the car market. Despite all the sanctions, wars and other obstacles, this market is, by and large, global. One way or another, car prices in one country affect car prices in other countries. Cunning businessmen will always find a way to buy cheaper in order to sell at a higher price, even if this means transporting goods across oceans and continents. Therefore, Ivan became a competitor, firstly, to all retail car sellers in the world, and secondly, to all retail car buyers in the world. This competition is not direct, like that of market traders sitting at adjacent counters, or buyers standing opposite them, but indirect. But nevertheless, it plays a role in determining the purchase price of the goods and Ivan’s behavior. In addition, Ivan has become a direct competitor to all buyers in the territory where he is able to purchase a car without additional effort, and, accordingly, to all sellers from there.

The difference between the above market participants is huge. Some work professionally with cars, others only drive them. Some people want to get rid of their car and get money, while others want to do the opposite. For one group of buyers, cars are vital, for another they represent only luxury and excess. One group of sellers is on the verge of ruin, another is thriving. And so on. But what do they all, sellers and buyers, have in common, in what ways are they identical?

Perhaps someone will say that they all want to make an exchange. However, even in this they at least fall into two unequal groups: some want to exchange money for goods, while others, on the contrary, want to exchange goods for money. But in terms of the nature of the exchange itself, all participants are similar, since they strive to complete it for their own benefit.

What is benefit in terms of commodity-money exchange? Any marketer and shopaholic will tell you that the buyer’s benefit is to purchase a product “below the market,” that is, at a price below the market average for a given product or a given group of products with similar consumer characteristics. Or simpler: buy cheaper than your neighbor.

But here there are nuances that make this formulation cheating. Firstly , the price offer on the market visible to buyers does not always reflect real selling prices, especially average ones. Products are often displayed at deliberately inflated prices to create the illusion of their high cost and spur demand during so-called promotions and discounts. In short, figuring out the real “market price” is not that easy. Rosstat, for example, sends its agents every month with a form to fill out to stores, which results in, to put it mildly, a strange picture of average prices. Secondly , the similarity of consumer characteristics almost never means the sameness of real consumer qualities. These characteristics themselves partly serve to cover up and disguise information about the technology of production of a product, materials, composition and similar data, by which one can at least indirectly judge how and how long it will last, what its consumer qualities are. And in general, the average buyer is not able to understand such issues, so among “active consumers” various reviews, recommendations and other additional sources of awareness have become extremely popular, which, of course, also inevitably become a means of marketing, that is, deception.

Objectively, economically, benefit is an increase in value as a result of an act of exchange . If, as a result of the purchase, the value, as if “materialized” in the car, turns out to be higher than the value expressed by the amount of money paid, it means that Ivan made a profitable transaction for himself as a market participant. It is clear that this situation is an exception, since the seller in this case must sell the car below cost, or better yet, below production cost. On a huge scale of market transactions, this happens in extremely rare cases. But the funny thing is that finding and achieving such deals becomes a passion for some. This passion, like a virus, infects and also contributes to an artificial increase in demand due to fraud and fraud of sellers.

In general, it is almost impossible for our Ivan to win competition from an army of car sellers. But he can succeed in competition with similar buyers if he buys cheaper than others, or at least cheaper than the price that is truly average. It is precisely this situation that is presented as a benefit. But she hardly is. If a seller spends the whole day selling apples purchased for 40 rubles at a 50% discount for 100 rubles, and at the closing of the counter he released the last bags of 90 rubles to two or three lucky ones, then for him they are the same boobies as the rest.

Moreover, it should be understood that competition is not limited to the final stage of purchasing and selling goods. Competition permeates the entire “economic movement of society.” The manufacturer competes with banks, owners of land, if it does not belong to him, with sellers of equipment, raw materials, semi-finished products, and buyers. Buyers - with transport organizations and retail chains, and so on. The number of different economic agents and others is huge, and they all crave profit and gain.

It is private interest that is identical for all market participants, for all competitors, current and potential. The metamorphosis of private interest is that, on the one hand , everyone has it and it is the same for everyone (getting more by giving less), on the other hand , that its sameness is nothing more than a universal opposition, the opposition of people.

Nevertheless, the examples of competition depicted above do not look like something monstrous, just a means of distribution under the dominance of an enterprising minority over a tired and dragging majority. But the whole trick of capitalism is that when scaling this automobile-Apple war of all against all, the objective law of competition gives rise to the monsters of poverty, crises, wars, colonialism, terrorism and all other deformities of decaying imperialism.

Marx and Engels wrote in the Manifesto:

“The means of production and exchange, on the basis of which the bourgeoisie was formed, were created in feudal society. At a certain stage of development of these means of production and exchange, the relations in which the production and exchange of feudal society took place, the feudal organization of agriculture and industry, in a word, feudal property relations, no longer corresponded to the developed productive forces. They slowed down production instead of developing it. They became his shackles. They had to be broken, and they were broken. Their place was taken by free competition, with its corresponding social and political system, with the economic and political dominance of the bourgeois class. <...> The growing competition of the bourgeoisie among themselves and the trade crises it causes lead to the fact that workers' wages are becoming more and more unstable. <...> The organization of the proletarians into a class, and thereby into a political party, is being destroyed again every minute by competition between the workers themselves... Wage labor rests solely on the competition of workers among themselves.”

This does not mean that there was no competition between the feudal lords; all they did was wage endless wars for land - the main wealth of their era. Just a ruinous war for the sake of suppressing and destroying the power of competitors in neighboring lands is the most vivid and complete embodiment of the same social relationship of competition, which today is familiar to every seller and consumer, supplier and customer, banker and entrepreneur. However, capitalism has adjusted almost all production to the market; capitalism in general is the highest form of commodity production. Thus, competition has taken on a new form, firstly , it has become universal , that is, now literally all people participate in it as formally legally free subjects, and secondly , two sides have emerged in it: economic, market competition and others, in particularly political and ideological.

Market competition is recognized as the basis of capitalism and a healthy, beneficial phenomenon, while political and ideological (religious, ideological, cultural, etc.) competition seems to be on its own, and the causes of various problems and conflicts are constantly found in it. Let's say that now a group of imperialists led by the United States, the so-called collective West, is waging a war with the imperialist Russian Federation. But in bourgeois literature and propaganda it is difficult to find the economic background of both sides, but it is full of maxims about “Western values” and the “Russian world”. This is a clear example of how these two sides of competition are artificially separated to cover up real economic motives.

Economic competition is what distinguishes capitalism; it is a law of the capitalist mode of production .

Thus, Engels spoke about competition in his early work “Outline for a Critique of Political Economy” as follows.

“Since private property isolates everyone in his own rude isolation and since everyone still has the same interest as his neighbor, the landowner is hostile to the landowner, the capitalist to the capitalist, and the worker to the worker. In this hostility of identical interests, precisely because of their similarity, the immorality of the current state of humanity ends, and this completion is competition. The opposite of competition is monopoly. Monopoly was the battle cry of the mercantilists; competition was the battle cry of the liberal economists. It is not difficult to see that this opposition, in turn, is completely devoid of content. <…> After liberal political economy has done everything in its power to make hostility universal by destroying nationalities, to turn humanity into a herd of predatory animals - for what else are competitors? - devouring each other precisely because each has the same interest as the other - after such preliminary work, she still has only one step left to take on the path to her goal - the disintegration of the family. To achieve this, her own cute invention came to her aid - the factory system. The last vestige of common interest—the family community of property—has been undermined by the factory system and, at least here in England, is already in the process of decay. It has become a completely commonplace phenomenon that children who have barely become able to work, that is, who have reached the age of nine, spend their wages on themselves, see their father’s house as simply a paid shelter and give their parents a certain remuneration for board and housing. And how could it be otherwise? What else could have resulted from the separation of interests that underlies the system of free trade?

Once a principle is set in motion, it automatically permeates all its consequences, regardless of whether economists like it or not.

<...> The competition of individuals among themselves, the competition of capital with capital, labor with labor, etc., under these conditions, will be reduced to competition based on human nature and so far clearly explained only by Fourier - competition, which, with the elimination of opposing interests , will be limited to its inherent peculiar and reasonable sphere.”

We find something even more comprehensive in Marx:

“In manufacture, the iron law of strictly defined proportions and relationships distributes the working masses between various functions; on the contrary, the whimsical play of chance and arbitrariness determines the distribution of commodity producers and the means of their production between various branches of social labor. True, various spheres of production constantly strive for equilibrium, because, on the one hand, each commodity producer must produce use value, that is, satisfy a certain social need - moreover, the sizes of these needs are quantitatively different and the various needs are internally interconnected into one natural system - on the other hand, the law of value of goods determines what part of the working time at its disposal society is able to spend on the production of each given type of commodity. However, this constant tendency of the various spheres of production towards equilibrium is only a reaction against the constant disruption of this equilibrium. The rule that operates in the division of labor within the workshop a priori and systematically, in the division of labor within society acts only a posteriori [retrospectively], as an internal, blind natural necessity, overcoming the disorderly arbitrariness of commodity producers and perceived only in the form of barometric fluctuations of market prices. The manufacturing division of labor presupposes the unconditional power of the capitalist over people who form simple links in the aggregate mechanism belonging to him; the social division of labor pits independent commodity producers against each other, recognizing no other authority other than competition, other than that coercion that is the result of the struggle of their mutual interests - just as in the animal world there is a bellum omnium contra omnes [war of all against all] to a greater or lesser extent the condition for the existence of all species. Therefore, the bourgeois consciousness, which glorifies the manufacturing division of labor, the lifelong attachment of the worker to any one operation and the unconditional subordination of the partial worker to capital as an organization of labor that increases its productive power, - this same bourgeois consciousness with equal fervor denounces all conscious social control and regulation the social process of production as an attack on the inviolable rights of property, freedom and the self-determining “genius” of the individual capitalist. It is very characteristic that the inspired apologists of the factory system do not find a stronger objection to the general organization of social labor than the indication that such an organization would turn the whole of society into a factory” (“Capital. Critique of Political Economy”).

The struggle of mutual interests, as in the animal world, is what competition is!

To be continued…

A. Redin
04/7/2024

https://prorivists.org/92_competition/

Google Translator
"There is great chaos under heaven; the situation is excellent."

Post Reply